高管薪酬和激励外文翻译_第1页
高管薪酬和激励外文翻译_第2页
高管薪酬和激励外文翻译_第3页
高管薪酬和激励外文翻译_第4页
高管薪酬和激励外文翻译_第5页
已阅读5页,还剩12页未读 继续免费阅读

下载本文档

版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领

文档简介

高管薪酬和激励外文翻译 外文题目 Executive Compensation And Incentives 外文出处 Acodemy of Management Perspectives,20062:p25-40 外文作者 Martin J. Conyon 原文:Executive Compensation And IncentivesMartin J. Conyon Executive compensation is a complex and controversial subject. For many years, academics, policymakers, and the media have drawn attention to the high levels of pay awarded to U.S. chief executive officers CEOs, questioning whether they are consistent with shareholder interests. Some academics have further argued that flaws in CEO pay arrangements and deviations from shareholders interests are widespread and considerable. For example, Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried provide a lucid account of the managerial power view and accompanying evidence. Marianne Bertrand and Sendhil Mullainathan too provide an analysis of the skimming view of CEO pay. In contrast, John Core et al. present an economic contracting approach to executive pay and incentives, assessing whether CEOs receive inefficient pay without performance. In this paper, we show what has happened to CEO pay in the United States. We do not claim to distinguish between the contracting and managerial power views of executive pay. Instead, we document the pattern of executive pay and incentives in the United States, investigating whether this pattern is consistent with economic theory. The Context: Who Sets Executive Pay Before examining the empirical evidence presented in this paper, it is important to consider the pay-setting process and who sets executive pay. The standard economic theory of executive compensation is the principal-agent model. The theory maintains that firms seek to design the most efficient compensation packages possible in order to attract, retain, and motivate CEOs, executives, and managers. In the agency model, shareholders set pay. In practice, however, the compensation committee of the board determines pay on behalf of shareholders. A principal shareholder designs a contract and makes an offer to an agent CEO/ manager. Executive compensation ameliorates a moral hazard problem i.e., manager opportunism arising from low firm ownership. By using stock options, restricted stock, and long-term contracts, shareholders motivate the CEO to imize firm value. In other words, shareholders try to design optimal compensation packages to provide CEOs with incentives to align their mutual interests. This is the contract approach to executive pay. Following Core, Guay, and Larcker, an efficient or optimal contract is one “that imizes the net expected economic value to shareholders after transaction costs such as contracting costs and payments to employees. An equivalent way of saying this is that contracts minimize agency costs.” Several important ideas flow from this definition. First, the contract reduces manager opportunism and motivates CEO effort by providing incentives through risky compensation such as stock options. Second, the optimal contract does not imply a “perfect” contract, only that the firm designs the best contract it can in order to avoid opportunism and malfeasance by the manager, given the contracting constraints it faces. Third, in this arrangement, the firm does not necessarily eliminate agency costs, but instead evaluates the marginal benefits of implementing the contract relative to the marginal costs of doing so. Improvements in regulation or corporate governance can possibly alter these costs and benefits, making different contracts desirable. Moreover, what is efficient at one point in time may not be at another. Improvements in board governance, for example by adding independent directors, may lead to different patterns of compensation, stock, and option contracts that are desirable for one firm but not another. An alternative theory is that CEOs set pay. This is the managerial power view, exemplified recently by Bebchuk and Fried. In this theory, the board and compensation committee cooperate with the CEO and agree on excessive compensation, settling on contracts that are not in shareholders interests. This excess pay constitutes an economic rent, an amount greater than necessary to get the CEO to work in the firm. The constraints the CEOs face are reputation loss and embarrassment if caught extracting rents, what Bebchuk and Fried call “outrage costs.” Outrage matters because it can impose on CEOs both market penalties such as devaluation of a managers reputation and social costs?the social costs come on top of the standard market costs. They argue that market constraints and the social costs coming from excessively favorable pay arrangements are not sufficient in preventing considerable deviations from optimal contracting. Executive Compensation There is substantial disclosure about U.S. executive compensation. The Securities and Exchange Commission SEC expanded and enhanced disclosure rules for U.S. executives in 1992. As a result, the proxy statements of firms contain considerable detail on stock ownership, stock options, and all components of compensation for the top five corporate executives. There are four basic components to executive pay, each having been the subject of much research. First, executives receive a base salary, which is generally benchmarked against peer firms. Second, they enjoy an annual bonus plan, usually based on accounting performance measures. Third, executives receive stock options, which represent a right, but not the obligation, to purchase shares in the future at some pre-specified exercise price. Lastly, pay includes additional compensation such as restricted stock, long-term incentive plans, and retirement plans. Executive Incentives We now turn to executive incentives and the link between pay and firm performance. The evidence demonstrates that executive compensation and the fraction of pay accounted for by option grants increased during the 1990s. Principal-agent theory predicts that a firm designs contracts in order to yield optimal incentives, therefore motivating the CEO to imize shareholder value. In designing the contract, the firm recognizes the CEO is risk averse. Thus, imposing greater incentives requires more pay to compensate the agent for increased risk. In the previous section, the paper demonstrated that CEO pay has increased. Next, we examine what has happened to CEO incentives. The analysis shows that executives have considerable equity incentives that create a strong and increasing link between CEO wealth and firm performance. This finding seems at odds with the notion that executive pay and performance are decoupled. It is, however, consistent with other economic evidence, showing that the link between pay and performance has been increasing in the United States. Executives receive incentives from several sources. They receive financial incentives from salary and bonus, as well as new grants of options and restricted stock, which together measure flow compensation. They also receive incentives from changes in their aggregate holdings of stock and options in the firm, as described in detail below. Finally, the probability of termination because of poor performance gives the CEO an incentive to pursue strategies that imize firm value. In this case, if terminated, an executive suffers reputation loss and human capital devaluation in the managerial labor market. However, this paper?consistent with other recent research in financial economics?focuses on compensation and equity incentives, leaving aside career concerns and the labor market for managerial talent. In other words, it restricts attention to financial incentives. The key to understanding financial incentives is recognizing that they arise from the entire portfolio of equity holdings and not simply from current pay. Equity incentives, then, are the incentives to increase the stock price arising from the managers ownership of financial securities in the firm. For example, a CEO may receive 100,000 options this year, which might add to 400,000 options granted in previous years, for a total of 500,000 options held. If the stock price decreases, then the value of the 100,000 options granted this year declines? but so does the value of the options accumulated from previous years. Since the CEO will care about the whole stock of 500,000 options, not simply this years 100,000, executive compensation received in any given year provides only a partial picture of CEO wealth and incentives. To understand CEO incentives fully, it is important to focus on the aggregate amount of shares, restricted stock, and stock options that the CEO owns in the firm. The evidence shows that CEOs have plenty of financial incentives, arising primarily from CEO ownership of stock and options in their firms. Again, we would stress that such financial incentives are only one factor motivating executives. Agents are as likely to be motivated by intrinsic factors of the job, career concerns, social norms, tournaments, and the like. One problem with stock options and other forms of incentive pay is not that they provide too few incentives, but that they may lead to unintended consequences. It is well known that incentives can bring about behavior by the agent that was unanticipated by the principal. In a classic paper, Steven Kerr highlighted the folly of rewarding A while hoping for B. In short, he articulated the notion that one gets what one pays for. If one rewards activity A and not B, then people will exert effort on A, while de-emphasizing B. Kerr illustrates his point with an array of examples from politics, industry, and human resource management. In general, this is a problem of providing appropriate incentives to agents engaging in multiple tasks. More recently, Robert Gibbons has discussed the design of incentive programs recognizing such problems. Another problem with incentive compensation is that it may encourage opportunistic behavior by managers, manipulation of performance measures, or cheating. The powerful and often unanticipated effects of financial incentives on economic outcomes have been documented in diverse contexts such as classroom teaching, real estate markets, vehicle inspection markets, and the behavior of physicians. In the corporate context, David Yermack demonstrates that CEOs opportunistically time the award of option grants around earnings announcements in order to increase their compensation. Other studies find that private information is used by executives to engineer abnormally large option exercises and hence the payouts from those options. In addition, studies show that firms with more incentives are associated with greater earnings manipulation. Recent studies show that the likelihood of a firm being the target of fraud allegations is positively correlated with option incentives. In short, options and incentive pay may motivate managerial behavior that is not always anticipated or ideal. When designing compensation plans, boards must be aware of the unwanted as well as beneficial effects of incentives. Conclusions Executive compensation is a controversial and complex subject that continues to attract the attention of the media, policymakers, and academics. Contract theory predicts that shareholders use pay to provide incentives for the CEO to focus on imizing long-term firm value. Since CEOs have relatively low ownership of firm shares, they might otherwise behave opportunistically. An alternative theoretical perspective, the managerial power view, is that CEOs control the pay-setting process and set their own pay. This theory predicts that compliant compensation committees and boards provide CEOs with excess pay or compensation “rents” and that contracts are suboptimal from the shareholders perspective. Distinguishing between these two theories is an important challenge for future research. This paper provides evidence on what has happened to CEO pay between 1993 and 2003. It shows that total compensation increased significantly over this period. Grants of stock options to CEOs and executives are the main driver of CEO pay gains. The paper also documents that CEOs have important financial incentives. These arise from the portfolio of firm stock and options owned by the CEO. The important point is that, if the stock price declines significantly, the value of the CEOs assets falls. Analogously, if asset prices increase, so does CEO wealth. In consequence, the wealth of the CEO varies with the stock price performance of the firm. An important research challenge is to fully understand the potentially unintended consequences of providing greater incentives to agents. In practice, CEO compensation contracts are determined by compensation committees that may have conflicting incentives to align with the CEO leading to suboptimal contracts and excess pay or with shareholders leading to optimal contracts and appropriate pay. The analysis in this paper illustrates that U.S. boards and compensation committees are becoming more independent measured by fewer insider directors and a greater number of outside directors. The evidence shows that the presence of affiliated directors on the compensation committee an instance where greater managerial power is expected does not lead to greater CEO pay or fewer CEO incentives. In summary, high pay itself is not evidence of inefficient contracts but may simply reflect the market for CEOs and the pay necessary to attract, retain, and motivate talented individuals. Boards of directors need to design compensation contracts to align the interests of owners with managers. One test of whether the corporate governance system is working appropriately, including executive compensation arrangements, is to evaluate economic performance. Holmstrom and Kaplan investigate the state of U.S. corporate governance in the wake of corporate scandals. They conclude that the U.S. economy has performed well, both on an absolute basis and relative to other countries over about two decades. Importantly, the economy has been robust even after the scandals were revealed. This is not to deny that improvements in governance arrangements may be beneficial. Furnishing CEOs with appropriate compensation and incentives is desirable for a healthy economy. However, ensuring that the contracting process is not corrupted is an important goal for corporate governance extracts译文: 高管薪酬和激励 Martin J. Conyon 高管薪酬是一种既复杂又有争议的话题。多年来,学者、决策者和媒体注意到了美国首席执行官的高薪酬水平的支付,并质疑他们是否与股东利益保持一致。一些学者更进一步指出在首席执行官的薪酬安排和偏离股东利益上的缺陷是普遍和值得考虑的。比如说,Lucian Bebchuk和Jesse Fried提供了一个明晰的账户管理权力观点并附上了证据。Marianne Bertrand和Sendhil Mullainathan也提供了“揭开首席执行官薪酬面纱”的分析。相反,John Core等一些美国联盟提出了一种经济承包方式来处理高管薪酬与激励,以此来评估首席执行官是否接受低效率绩效的薪酬支付。我们不要求区分经济承包和管理权力观点来支付高管薪酬。相反,我们用文件证明在美国的高管薪酬激励模式,调查这种模式是否与经济理论相一致。 背景:谁设置高管薪酬? 在审查本文提供的实验性证据前,考虑薪酬的设置过程和由谁来设置高管薪酬是非常重要的。经济理论中的高管薪酬标准是委托-代理模型。该模型认为,公司力争去设计最有效最合理的薪酬包去吸引、留住并激励首席执行官、高管及管理者们。在代理模型中,由股东设置薪酬。然而,实际上董事会薪酬委员会是站在股东的利益上来决定薪酬的。由主要的股东设计出一份薪酬方案给代理人(总裁或经理)。改善高管薪酬道德风险问题(也就是经理机会主义)起因于低稳固性的所有权。股东通过股票期权、受限股票和长期合同来激励总裁实现公司价值最大化。换句话说,股东设法去设计最佳的薪酬包来激励总裁以达成他们共同的利益。这就是类似高管薪酬的方案。在Core,Guay和Larcker之后,一个有效的(或最佳的)方案是“在扣除交易成本(例如承包成本)和支付给雇员薪酬后给股东最大的预期经济价值。相同的说法就是缩减代理成本使其最小化。” 几个重要思想来自于这个说法。首先,该方案通过提供风险激励薪酬如股票期权来减少经理机会主义并且激励总裁的努力。第二,最佳方案并不意味着“完美”方案,只是公司为了避免经理机会主义和不当行为而设计的最合适的方案,以此作为承包的约束。第三,在这种情况下,公司并不一定消除代理成本,而是评估实施这种方案(边际)收益以及这么做所涉及的(边际)成本。改善公司管理或规章制度可能改变这些成本和收益,产生不一样的令人满意的方案。此外,在一个时间点有效在另一个时间点就无效。提高董事会管理,比如通过增加独立董事,可能产生令这个公司而非其他公司满意的不同类型的薪酬、股票和期权合约。 另一种理论是由总裁设置薪酬。这是管理权力的观点,以Bebchuk和Fried为最新代表。在这个理论中,董事会和薪酬委员会与总裁合作并同意提供超额薪酬,按合约授予而非根据股东利益。这种超额薪酬支付构成了一种远远大于聘请该总裁来公司工作的必须薪酬的经济租金。在提取租金后约束总裁的将是名誉损失和尴尬,这被Bebchuk和Fried称为“暴行成本”。暴行能通过市场惩罚(经理名誉的货币贬值)和要求高标准市场成本的社会成本这两项来给总裁施压。他们认为来自极度良好的薪酬支付安排的市场约束和社会成本是在预防相当大的最优承包偏离时的资金不足。 高管薪酬 有个关于美国高管薪酬的本质披露。美国证券交易委员会在1992年扩大和提高了对美国高管们的披露尺度。结果,代理公司控制着相当大的股份所有权、股票期权和前五高管团体所有的薪酬组成。这里有四种高管薪酬的基本部件,每一种都有许多研究。首先,高管们接受基本薪资,一般该基本薪资在同行公司中是基准。其次,他们享受年终分红计划,通常基于分期业绩考核。第三,高管们接受股票期权,它作为一项权利而非义务,以预先规定的合约价格在未来购买股票。最后,薪酬包括额外补偿比如限制性股票、长期激励计划和养老金计划。 高管激励 我们现在来看高管激励以及薪酬和企业绩效之间的联系。证据表明在20世纪90年代期间高管薪酬和小部分未予以说明的选择性补助金增加了。委托-代理理论预测一个公司设计承包契约是为了出产最佳的激励,因此激励总裁去实现股东价值最大化。在设计承包契约过程中,公司认为总裁就是规避风险。因此,需要更多激励去补偿代理人以规避增加着的风险。在上文中论证了总裁薪酬是

温馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
  • 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
  • 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
  • 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
  • 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。

评论

0/150

提交评论