




版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
1、 the political economy of chinese-style privatization: motives and constraintsguy s. liu a, pei sun b,# , wing thye woo ca. brunel business school, brunel university, the united kingdomb. the business school, university of nottingham, the united kingdomc. department of economics, university of calif
2、ornia, davis, the united statesforthcoming in world development, 2006# corresponding author: nottingham university business school, jubilee campus wollaton road nottingham ng8 1bb, england, u.k. tel: +44 (0)115 84 66361 fax: +44 (0)115 84 66667 email address: pei.sunnottingham.ac.uksummarythe paper
3、examines how the privatization of chinese state-owned enterprises (soes) can be successfully triggered and completed. by identifying the motives of local government leaders and the constraints facing them during transition, we conclude that: first, whether local governments are motivated to privatiz
4、e their soes depends on if the ownership transfer is expected to stimulate sufficiently high growth of local tax revenues without sacrificing bureaucrats private control benefits. second, a specific privatization program can succeed only if it manages to satisfy the managerial cooperation constraint
5、, the workers compensation constraint, and the bank debt-servicing constraint. the motives-cum-constraints political economy approach offers an important explanation for the pace and scope of ongoing chinese-style privatization.keywords: privatization, enterprise reform, political economy, local gov
6、ernment, chinaacknowledgementthe authors greatly appreciate the access to the year 2004 enterprise survey data permitted by the institute of enterprise research, the development research center of state council, peoples republic of china. we are also indebted to stephen green, xiaoxuan liu and mike
7、wright for their valuable comments, and to the anonymous reviewers of world development, whose constructive advice has helped to improve the quality of the paper significantly. the usual disclaimer applies.1. introductionunlike the big-bang mass privatization approach adopted by the eastern european
8、 and former soviet union (eefsu) countries, the chinese government until the mid 1990s was still trying to improve the soe performance by establishing market-oriented incentives1 while maintaining its ownership and control over a great majority of industrial enterprises. since then, china has entere
9、d a new phase of enterprise reform: the government has explicitly pursued a 2-r strategy retain government control of large enterprises that operate in the strategic sectors and retreat from small and medium-sized enterprises that operate in highly competitive markets (e.g. green and liu, 2005). wit
10、h regard to the restructuring of large soes, corporatization and stock flotation are the key measures used to privatize a fraction of government cash flow rights, in return for funds to the extent that the government is still able to maintain ultimate corporate control (liu and sun, 2005b). meanwhil
11、e, hundreds of thousands of small and medium soes at local level have been granted privatization permission during the last decade. moreover, a large amount of evidence shows that the major players behind the rise of privatization are local governments, especially those at municipal and county level
12、s (tenev and zhang, 2002; garnaut, song, tenev and yao 2005; oecd, 2005).2then natural questions arise on what motivates the government to relinquish its control of industrial firms, what constraints the smooth progress of privatizations, and what economic and socio-political factors affect the dyna
13、mics of government-initiated privatization programs. unfortunately, in comparison with a vast amount of literature devoted to assessing the extent of success of privatization by examining the profitability and operational efficiency of privatized enterprises, in-depth analyses of the factors that in
14、itially trigger privatization and further constrain its progress are relatively inadequate both in general theoretical formulations and in empirical studies.amongst a limited number of existing works relevant to the research questions just posed, yarrow (1999) makes a general conjecture that the wor
15、ldwide spread of privatization during the 1980s and 1990s can largely be attributed to the escalating government expenditure relative to gdp growth, together with the increasing cost of government finance. so governments privatize soes in order to ease their fiscal pressures. this fiscal pressure vi
16、ew seems to be a parsimonious answer, but it fails to capture the deep political economy nature of the privatization decision-making process. for instance, biais and perotti (2002) provide a model showing how privatization can be employed as a strategic policy by incumbent politicians to maximize th
17、eir probability of winning the re-election.3 although not directly applicable to the chinese context, the political-benefit view is illuminating in reminding us that political and institutional factors do have a direct bearing on government officials privatization decision. moving to the developing
18、country context, bienen and waterbury (1989) not only mention the significance of fiscal austerity and international donor duress in triggering privatization, but argue that to assess the constraints on and possibilities for privatization, one must have a clear picture of the gains and losses that w
19、ill be sustained by the constituent elements of dominant political coalitions (p.618). even in nonelectoral systems, leaders must find enough support or create new bases of support to sustain privatization policies (p.629). such insights are echoed and further elaborated by the world bank (1995) in
20、a chapter entitled the politics of soe reform. on the basis of a comprehensive study of the reform experience in the developing world up to the early 1990s, the policy research report generalizes some essential conditions of a successful privatization program, notably the political desirability from
21、 the leaders viewpoint and the political feasibility ensured by government leaders in withstanding opposition from potential losers. this paper closely follows the political-benefit view suggested by the aforementioned literature in general; and the discussion of motives and constraints involved in
22、chinas privatization in the last decade serves to update and enrich our understanding of the critical issues concerning political desirability and feasibility in particular. in fact, the world bank (1995) did touch upon the case of transition china when discussing the two conditions. but obviously i
23、ts assessment was grounded on the extremely limited, if any, formal private ownership presence in the chinese industrial sector in the late 1980s and early 1990s. the transformation of the industrial landscape since the mid 1990s, however, prompts us to rethink how the incentive structure within the
24、 authoritarian regime and the change of wider institutional environments can interact to significantly alter the desirability and feasibility of privatization in transition china.4in the paper we aim to answer the why-privatize question by identifying the unique institutional settings that have shap
25、ed the incentive structure of the privatization-friendly chinese local government leaders. based on an analytical framework that integrates the extant china-based studies, we maintain that local government leaders will be keen to privatize their soes only if they can assure themselves of both higher
26、 growth of fiscal revenues and the retention of their private benefits from the privatized firms.moreover, the willingness of government officials to privatize soes alone does not necessarily translate into the success of privatization programs in practice. rather, they are subject to a series of en
27、tangled economic and socio-political constraints that are always of country-specific nature, since privatization itself means a complete reshuffling of the extant interest structure concerning not only governments, but also managers, workers, and creditors. in the paper we highlight some essential c
28、onstraints imposed by the key stakeholders in privatization, namely the managerial cooperation constraint, the workers compensation constraint, and the bank debt-servicing constraints. in particular, for a detailed privatization plan to proceed smoothly, government leaders must be able to enlist the
29、 cooperation of the soe managers, compensate the workers to an extent they deem sufficient, and guarantee the payment of existing bank loans after the restructuring. the rest of the paper is organized as follows: section two provides an aggregate picture of the latest ownership structure in the chin
30、ese industrial sector. section three is devoted to an in-depth analysis of the evolution of institutional environments during the 1990s china, which shapes the incentive structure of local leaders in making their privatization decision. based on the recently introduced integrative framework, section
31、 four illustrates the conditions that need to be satisfied to make local leaders committed to privatization. section five moves on to identify the key constraints that need to be overcome if the desire for ownership transfer is to be turned into reality. the sixth section presents further statistica
32、l evidence in support of the motives and constraints propositions. section seven concludes.2. the ownership transformation of the chinese industrial sector: latest developmentsmore than twenty-five years of economic reform has completely transformed chinas industrial landscape to the extent that, at
33、 the beginning of the century, according to the official statistics shown in table 1, the private sector already accounted for more than 40% of national industrial output and employment, in comparison with the soe sector that now only accounts for less than one quarter in the two aggregate indicator
34、s. this is in stark contrast to the composition in 1980, when the state, collective and private sectors respectively contributed 76%, 23.5% and 0.5% of the national industrial output. <insert table 1 here>it is worth noting, however, that the official data acts, at best, as a crude estimate, s
35、ince the mixed ownership structure has become commonplace in corporate china, and is present in virtually all enterprises however they are classified in table 1. in particular, the collective sector shown in table 1 is a highly ambiguous ownership category, as a large number of listed and limited li
36、ability companies, or even the collective firms, are ultimately controlled by either government units or the private ones (e.g. liu & sun, 2005a, b). an early attempt to remedy the problem was undertaken by us through the use of the china statistical bureau 2001 national survey data. by combinin
37、g the survey data and the official statistics, we find that, in terms of ultimate ownership, the state, the collective, and the private in 2001 respectively accounted for 31%, 12% and 36% of chinas industrial output.5 subsequent estimation efforts in this respect, despite some arbitrary assumptions
38、that have to be made, have managed to illustrate a clear trend of ownership evolution from the late 1990s to the early 2000s (garnaut et al, 2005; oecd, 2005). for example, table 2 suggests a gradual but steady rise of the private sector during 1998-2003: by the end of 2003, domestic private firms h
39、ad gained an equal weight to that of the state-controlled ones in their contribution to chinas gdp. if we focus on the industrial/non-farm business sector, table 3 reports more rapid growth of the private sector and decline of state ownership during the same period, with the collective segment nearl
40、y halving.<insert table 2 and 3 here>it goes without saying that the change of ownership structure at the macro level is accompanied by significant divestment and transformation of the soes across industries and regions.6 while a complete record of soe ownership restructuring is not available
41、in china, the latest national-scale survey7 reveals both the pace and the main forces driving the restructuring, details of which are shown in table 4. it can readily be seen from the table that the pace of ownership restructuring was gradual but gained momentum at the start of the century. notwiths
42、tanding the potential over-sampling of non-restructured soes in our survey,8 more than 42% of firms have been fully or partially privatized during the whole period under investigation.9 and within the restructured firms, more than three quarters undertook the transformation during 2001-2003. regardi
43、ng the choice of full versus partial privatization, unfortunately only 997 firms reported the information. it is found that only 31.4% of the firms have undergone a full privatization so far, which suggests that a limited amount of control transfer has taken place.moreover, a breakdown of the sample
44、 soes based on central and local government affiliation indicates that it is local governments that have been keen to promote the ownership restructuring programs over the past few years. while less than one quarter of the centrally controlled soes in our sample experienced ownership restructuring,
45、more than one half of their local counterparts were already privatized by the mid 2004. the difference in the choice of full versus partial privatization is also significant in the sub-sample just mentioned: nearly 40% of the restructured local soes can be classified as full privatization, in contra
46、st to 10% in the transformed central soes.overall, the preceding data presentation implies two stylized facts on the pace and scope of chinas ownership restructuring over the last decade. first, the progress of the transformation is gradual but steady, with a mixture of full and partial privatizatio
47、n arrangements. second, soes controlled by local governments take the lead in the transition process both in terms of scale measured by the percentage of firms having been restructured, and of depth indicated by the proportion of firms that have undergone full privatization. 3. changing incentive st
48、ructure of local government leaders: an institutional environment perspectivegiven the latest developments of the ongoing privatization in china, in the section we examine the multifaceted institutional forces responsible for the emergence of the pro-privatization attitude on the part of local gover
49、nment leaders. while several pieces of work have already touched upon the causes of privatization in china, they either omit some of the key institutional factors driving privatization (qian & roland, 1998; cao, qian, & weingast, 1999; li, li, & zhang, 2000), or amount to little more tha
50、n a collection of loosely knitted hypotheses (garnault et al, 2005; guo & yao, 2005). specifically, qian & roland (1998), cao et al (1999), and li et al (2000) address the question by means of the following reasoning: first, the fiscal and monetary recentralization in the 1990s contributed t
51、o the significant hardening of budget constraints on local governments, which means that they now have to assume the primary responsibility for local economies, in correspondence with their control of independent revenue sources granted by the 1980s decentralization. second, the intensification of c
52、ross-regional competition in product markets is the driving force behind local governments privatizing their enterprises to supply more incentives to managers and to improve the enterprises competitiveness, which in turn increase their fiscal revenue. these arguments do touch upon the fundamental co
53、ntributing forces that trigger the chinese-style privatization, but as will be shown below, the combination of fiscal reform and intensified market competition itself is still not adequate to nurture the appropriate conducive institutional environment for privatization. more crucially, none of them
54、explicitly analyze the cadre management system during the reform era and the private benefits the local bureaucrats can capture from the state and privatized firms, which can play a critical part in their decision-making. commissioned by the ifc/world bank, garnaut et al (2005) offer a more up-to-da
55、te review of the latest ownership restructuring process in china. with respect to the causes of privatization, they have identified the main players during the institutional change and grouped the incentives of privatization into several hypotheses. in their companion paper, guo & yao (2005) use
56、 firm-level panel data to test the validity of the hypotheses.10 although the acceptance of some hypotheses whilst rejecting the others is informative to those who are interested in chinas privatization, their analysis lacks a general theoretical framework that can integrate these hypotheses in a sy
57、stematic fashion, not to mention the ad hoc classification of the hypotheses themselves. building on the existing literature on the complex privatization process in china, the paper constructs an integrative and coherent theoretical framework which focuses on the dynamic interaction between the ince
58、ntive structure of local government leaders and the changing institutional environment. on the one hand, the explicit specification of the payoff structure of local leaders enhances the analytical clarity of existing analyses. previous studies on the evolution of the institutional environment, on th
59、e other hand, are systematically organized in our framework to highlight their far-reaching impacts upon the leaders decision-making through their own payoff structure. the rest of the section is then devoted to a detailed discussion of the institutional environment relevant to the chinese-style privatizati
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
评论
0/150
提交评论