




版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
RecyclinginaGlobalizedEconomy
EugénieJoltreauandLuisSarmiento
WorkingPaper25-19
July2025
PAGE
1
RecyclinginaGlobalizedEconomy∗
EugénieJoltreau1,2,* LuisSarmiento1,2,3
Developingacirculareconomythroughwasterecyclinghasemergedasaparadigmforconservingnonrenewableresources.Butwhatdoesimplementingacirculareconomymeaninthecontextofglobalizedeconomies?Wastegeneratedbyconsumption,in-cludingimports,oftenmisalignswithnationalproductionandexportmaterialneeds.Thismaterialmismatch,termed"materialimbalances,"alongwithvariationsinwastedisutility,costs,andaccesstovirginresourcesacrosscountries,shapeslocalandin-ternationaltradestrategiesrelatedtowaste.Thispaperoffersanewperspectiveonrecyclingpolicies,emphasizinginternationaltradeandnationalmaterialimbal-ances.Wetheoreticallycharacterizetheexistenceofawastemarketforrecyclinganddemonstratethatlocalrecyclingincentivepoliciescandriveorreducewasteexportsdependingontheirdesign.Additionally,weshowboththeoreticallyandempiricallythatrelativematerialimbalancesbetweencountriesareakeydeterminantofwastetradeforrecycling.
JELcodes:Q53;H23;L33;L51
Keywords:CircularEconomy,InternationalTradeofWaste,EnvironmentalPolicy
Acknowledgements:E.J.acknowledgesfundingbytheEuropeanUnionundertheHorizonEuroperesearchandinnovationprogram,projectCircEUlar(GANo.101056810).
1RFF-CMCCEuropeanInstituteonEconomicsandtheEnvironment,Milan,Italy.
2CentroEuro-MediterraneoSuiCambiamentiClimatici,Lecce,Italy.
3BancodeMéxico,Merida,Mexico.
*Correspondingauthor.E-mail:
eugenie.joltreau@cmcc.it
∗
WethankDominikWiedenhoferandJanStreeckforsharingthematerialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO)modeldatawithus.WethankWeiGuoandRouhanSongfortheirhelpwiththereportsoftheChineseMinistryofCommerce.WethanktheparticipantsofEEA-ESEM2021fortheirhelpfulcommentsandparticipantsfromthe2022seminarofUniversitéParisDauphine,PSL,andCEE-M(INRAE).
Wearesolelyresponsibleforanyerrorsinthemanuscriptandreportnoconflictsofinterest.
PAGE
2
Introduction
Thecirculareconomyisoftendiscussedfromlocaltonationallevels(Korhonen,HonkasaloandSeppälä,2018);however,materialflowsexistwithintheframeworkofinternationaltrade.Globaltradecancreatemismatchesbetweenwastegenerationandthelocationswherematerialsareneededforproduction.Forinstance,somecountriesgenerateexcesswastematerialsthatcouldprovideinputsforindustriesinothernations.
Atthesametime,secondarymaterialsfromconsumption(wasteandrecycledmaterials)aretradedglobally.Asizeableglobalwastemarketexists—nearlyUSD100billionand218milliontons(2016value;OECD,2018).Ascountriesandregionsoftenimplementpolicieswithoutconsideringtheinternationalnatureofmaterialflows,weaimtounderstandthedeterminantsoftheglobalwastemarketforrecyclinganditsrelationtonationalrecyclingpoliciesandupstreamglobalization.
Wedeveloptheconceptofmaterialimbalance,definedasthemismatchbetweenmaterialsneededforproductionandwastegeneratedfromconsumption.Wethenformulateatheoreticalmodeltocharacterizetheinternationalmarketforpostconsumptionwaste,emphasizingitsinteractionwithnationalrecyclingpoliciesandmaterialimbalances.Finally,weempiricallytestthelinkbetweencountry-pairmaterialimbalancesandwastetrade.
Theliteratureonwastetradehasprimarilyfocusedonthewastehavenhypothesisandex-portsfordisposal(Copeland,1991;Baggs,2009;Kellenberg,2010,2012;EggerandKeuschnigg,2024),illegaltradeflows(Copeland,1991;Bernard,2015;Sun,2019)andwastetradeforreuse(YokooandKinnaman,2013;Bernard,2015);weprovidethefirstcharacterizationofinterna-tionalwastetradeforrecycling.Understandingthisiscrucialbecausereusemeetsconsumptionneeds,whereasrecyclablewasteservesasaproductioninput.Thisdistinctionimpliesdifferentdynamicswithinthevaluechain.Wefurthercontributetotheliteraturebyanalyzingtheeffectsofnationalrecyclingpoliciesinthecontextofglobalizedmaterialflows,suchasDussauxandGlachant(2019),García-BarragánandZelity(2019)andEggerandKeuschnigg(2024).1Toourknowledge,thisisthefirstarticleintheinternationaltradeandcirculareconomyliteraturetoutilizetheconceptofmaterialimbalancetocharacterizeinternationalmarketsforwasteandrecycledmaterials.
Webeginbymotivatingthetheoreticalmodelwithaseriesofstylizedfactsaboutinternationaltradeinrecyclablematerials,includingplastics,glass,steelandiron,aluminum,andpaper.
1AppendixA.1presentsacompletediscussionofthewastetradeliterature.
PAGE
3
First,wedocumentthemagnitude,composition,anddirectionofglobaltradeflowsinwasteusingcustomdata.Weconcludethatthevolumeoftradeinrecyclablewasteissignificant,amountingto52megatonnes(Mt)in2016.Notably,asignificantshareofthis—exceeding50Mt—hasoriginatedfromhigh-incomecountriesandbeenexportedworldwidesincethe2000s.Next,weexaminematerialimbalances(materialneedsformanufacturingminuswastegeneratedbyconsumption).Wefindthathigh-incomecountrieshaveaproduction-dominatedmaterialimbalance(exceptforpaper),butonethattendstodecrease(thevolumeofwasteincreasesfasterthanproductiveneeds).Incontrast,therestoftheworldexperiencesasignificantaccelerationinmaterialneedscomparedtowasteproduction.Finally,wedemonstratethatrecyclingpoliciesandthewastemarketinteract.WeestimatetheelasticitybetweenwasteexportsandnationalrecyclingratesinEurope,rangingfroma20percentagepointincreaseintherecyclingratefora1percentincreaseinwasteexportsforislandnations,likeMaltaandCyprus,to5–10percentagepointsforlargereconomies.
Ourtheoreticalmodelanalyzescountries’trade,disposal,andrecyclingdecisionsbasedontheirmaterialimbalances,nationaleconomicconditions,andglobalmarketpriceswithinastaticframework.ItincorporatesresourceendowmentsinthespiritoftheHeckscher-Ohlinframework,withthekeydistinctionthatwasteendowmentsaredeterminedbyconsumptionpatterns,whicharethemselvesinfluencedbyexogenousinternationalflowsoffinalgoods.Unlikeaconventionalmarketforgoodsorpollution,thismodelfeaturesanambivalentpricethatcanfluctuatebetweenpositiveandnegativevalues.2Itmakesseveralassumptions,includingashortageofprimarymaterials,asdocumentedbyYoshidaetal.(2005)forChina.Itexcludestradeinvirginresourcestofocussolelyonthedownstreamsector.Weassumethatallwasteisrecyclableatagivencost.
Thefirstequilibriumconsidersacompetitiveextractionindustrywithrespecttorecycling.Wedefineawasteexporterprofilecharacterizedbylowcollectioncosts,highdisposalandrecyclingcosts,andawaste-dominatedmaterialimbalance,contrastingwiththewasteimporterprofile.Wefindthatawastemarketemergesbetweentwocountrieswhenmutuallybeneficialtradeop-portunitiesarisefromasymmetriesinmaterialimbalances,lowtransportcosts,andvariationsinwastecollection,recycling,anddisposalcosts.ThisinsighthelpsusunderstandthesignificantwastetradebetweenEuropeandAsia.Inthisequilibrium,ourtheoreticalmodeldemonstratesthattradedoesnotaffectglobalrecycling;wasteexportsmerelyshifttotheimportingcoun-try,wherethewasteisrecycled,substitutingfornationalwastecollectionandrecycling.ThisalignswithChina’sstatementsthatbanningwasteimportsaimedtostimulatedomesticrecycling
2Themodelconsidersillegaltradeasthemodel’sboundary;whenthepricebecomestoonegative,themarketcanbecomeadumpingmarket.
PAGE
4
(ISWA,2018)andwithdatafromtheChineseMinistryofCommerceindicatinganincreaseindomesticrecyclingafterbanningimports(AppendixA.10).Thisisarelevantfindingfortheliteratureandpublicdebates,whichfocusedonthewastehavenhypothesisandtradeinwastefordisposal(Copeland,1991;Kellenberg,2012)orconsideredtradeinwasteasawaytoincreaseglobalrecyclingwhileminimizingeconomiccosts(OECD,2018).Inaddition,themodelshowsthatpoliciesbasedoneconomicincentivesinthewaste-exportingcountrytendtofavorexportsoverlocalrecyclinguptoacertainthreshold—untilthenetenvironmentalbenefitsofrecyclingexceedtheresidualneedformaterials.Inthisequilibrium,incorporationratesaremoreefficientthanrecyclingtargetsinincreasinglocalrecyclingforawasteexporterprofile.
Thesecondequilibriumemergeswhenrecyclingbecomesmoresociallycompetitiveduetohigherdisposalcostsandlowerrecyclingcosts.Thisshiftreflectsthestrengtheningofrecyclingpoliciesinthewaste-exportingcountry.Thosepoliciesenhancelocalrecycling,whichsubstitutesforvirginresources.Theimpactonwasteexportsismorenuanced:althoughtherecyclingsubsidyreducesexports,thedisposaltaxnolongerhasanyinfluence.Thecollectionsubsidystimulatesexportsbydrivingdownwasteprices.However,iftheglobalwastepricedropstoosharply,itcanincentivizeillegaltradefordisposal.
Accordingtothefirstequilibriumandassumingtheequalizationofothervariables,3atrademarketforwasterecyclingemergeswhencountrieshavedifferentrelativematerialimbalances.Intheempiricalsection,wetestthismodelpredictionbyexamininghowmaterialimbalancesbetweentwocountriesaffectwastetradewithinagravitymodelframework.UsingaPoissonpseudo-maximumlikelihoodestimator(PPMLE),wefindanelasticityof0.8betweenrelativematerialimbalanceandwastetradeforrecyclablematerials.Thisresultremainssignificantacrossdifferentspecifications,estimators,andmaterials,confirmingourtheoreticalcontribution.
Ourresultshaveseveralpolicyimplications.Thetheoreticalmodelindicatesthatwasteimporterprofilesareeconomieswithhighmaterialneeds,lowerdisposalandrecyclingcosts,andunderde-velopedcollectionandsortingsystems.Thisprofilematchesdevelopingeconomies,asconfirmedbythestylizedfacts,raisingbothenvironmentalandethicalconcerns.Developedcountriesmaythusstrengthenlocalrecyclingsystemstodecreasewasteexportsandcombatresourcescarcity.However,themodelrevealsthatpoorlydesignedrecyclingpoliciesmayunintentionallyencour-agewasteexportswithoutimprovingdomesticrecycling.Boththetheoreticalandempiricalmodelsrecognizematerialimbalancesasakeyfactorinfluencingwastetrade.Toaddressthisis-sue,exportingcountriescanadoptstrategiessuchasincreasinglocalmaterialdemand—through
3collection,disposalandrecyclingcosts,andvirginresourceavailability
PAGE
5
reindustrialization,forexample—andreducingwastebypromotingconsumptionsufficiencyandextendingproductlifecycles.However,anypolicyaimedatboostingmaterialdemandmustalignwithglobalsustainabilitygoals,acknowledgingtheneedtoreduceoverallresourceusetorespectplanetaryboundaries(Rockströmetal.,2009).
Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows:Section2presentsstylizedfactsonthetradeinrecyclablewaste,Section3displaysthetheoreticalmodel,andSection4empiricallytestsourtheory.Section5concludes.
StylizedFacts
AMajorTradeinRecyclableWaste
Theinternationaltradeinwasteissubstantial.In2016,itaccountedfor0.6percentofglobaltradevalue(OECD,2018).Itmainlyconsistedofmetal,paper,andplasticwaste(OECD,2018).Whenfocusingtherecyclablewastematerialsconsideredinthispaper,4thisfigureisabout0.53percentofthetotalvalueofinternationaltrade,comparabletotheannualtradeincoal,medicalinstruments,orsemiconductorsforthatyear(OrganizationforEconomicComplexity,2016).
Figure1presentstheevolutionofwastevolumesin(a)andthebalanceofwastetradeacrossincomegroupsin(b).WeconstructthisfigureusingdatafromtheBACIdatabasefromtheCentred’EtudesProspectivesetd’InformationsInternationales.Wecategorizecountriesintohigh-incomeandrestoftheworldaccordingtotheWorldBankclassification.Wefocusonthefivemainrecyclablewasteproducts:plastics,paper,aluminum,glass,andsteel/iron.5
Thevolumeofwastetradegrewsteadilyfromthebeginningofthecenturyuntilthe2008financialcrisis,increasingfrom84to181Mt.Despitethemarkeddecreasein2009,from2010,tradevolumeshaveremainedstableat170–200Mtperyear.Themostimportantrecyclablematerialbyvolumetradedissteel/iron,followedbypaper,plastic,aluminum,andglass.Panel
b)depictsthebalanceofwastetradebetweenhigh-incomecountriesandtherestoftheworld.Thistimeseriesconfirmsresearchindicatingagrowingsupplyofrecyclablewastetradefromhigh-tolower-incomeeconomiesstartinginthe2000s(CEPII,2012).In2022,high-incomecountrieshadrecyclablewastetradesurplusesofupto72Mt.
Themarketforrecyclablewasteishighlyconcentrated.Thetop10countriesaccountfor67
4Weconsiderfivewastematerials:plastics,paper,aluminum,glass,andsteel/iron,aligningwithEuropeanUnionpackagingrecyclingrequirements(Directive2018/852).
5WepresentthedataworkandotherstatisticsinAppendixA.3.
PAGE
6
Figure1:RecyclableWasteVolumeandValues
Notes:Self-constructeddatawithfiguresfromtheBasepourl’AnalyseduCommerceInternational.HScodesareinAppendixA.3.
percentofglobalwasteexports.Theonlynon-high-incomecountryinthisgroupisRussia.ThemainexportersaretheUnitedStates,Germany,Japan,andGreatBritain,withglobalsharesof19,10,7,and7percent,respectively.Chinaisthelargestimporter,accountingfor13.8percentofallimportsbetween2001and2022,followedbyGermany,Turkey,India,andKorea.
CountriesExhibitingMaterialImbalances
Globalizationandspecializationcancreatematerialimbalancesbecausedifferentspecializationsrequirevaryingresourceamounts.Forinstance,aserviceeconomytypicallyusesfewermaterialsforproductioncomparedtoamanufacturing-focusedeconomy.Moreover,aserviceeconomythatconsumeslargequantitiesofmanufacturedgoodsmaygeneratemorewastefromconsumptionthanitproduces.Incontrast,aneconomycenteredonresource-intensiveproductioncanproducelesswastethanitconsumes.Otherfactorscontributetothesediscrepancies,suchasproductlife-span,whichaffectswasteoutput,andlevelsofeconomicgrowthandurbanization,whichinfluenceproductionneeds.
Todocumentandprovideevidenceofmaterialimbalances,weusedatafromthematerialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)modelfromWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024);Wiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Gram-mer,BaumgartandPlank(2024).Itisanadvanced,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelthatprovidesacomprehensiveframeworkforanalyzingmaterialstocksandflowsacrossvarioussectors.6
6Ittracksmaterialsfromextractionthroughprocessing,trade,andproductuse,ultimatelyleadingtorecycling
PAGE
7
Figure2showsthedifferencebetweenthematerialsembodiedintheproductionofdomesticmanufacturedgoods(includingexports)andthoseintheapparentconsumptionofmanufacturedgoods(includingimports).7Exceptforglass,high-incomecountriesexhibitadifferentialfavoringconsumptioninmostrecentyears.Incontrast,therestoftheworldshowsanincreasingsurplusrelatedtoproductiveneeds.Thisdiscrepancysuggestsagrowingdemandformaterialsintheproductionofmanufacturedgoodsindevelopingnations,especiallyforexports.
Figure2:MaterialImbalancefromFinalProductionandConsumption
Notes:Thisfigurepresentsthetimeseriesofmaterialimbalanceembeddedinthedifferencesbetweenproductiveneedsandconsumption.Weconstructthedatasetfromtheeconomy-wide,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelofmaterialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)developedbyWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024).Toconstructthetimeseries,weuseMISO2-reporteddataonmaterialsembodiedinfinalproduction(F78)minusmaterialembodiedinlocalconsumption(F89).Thatis,materialimbalancefromproductionandconsumptionisF78–F89andshowsthemismatchbetweenacountry’scontemporarymaterialneedsforitsproductionprocessesandthematerialsembeddedinconsumption.Oncewecalculatethisvalueforeachcountry,weaggregatebycountrygroupbysummingoverallthecountriesinthatgroupandyear.
However,ourmaterialimbalanceconceptfocusesonavailablewasteratherthanmaterialem-bodiedinconsumption(i.e.,itintegratesproductlife-spans).Forinstance,arapidlyurbanizingeconomymayexhibithighmaterialconsumption,butthesematerialscanremaininuseforanextendedperiod.Incontrast,amatureeconomythatconsumesfewerdurablegoodsgenerateswastemorequickly.Figure3illustratesthedifferencebetweenmaterialsembodiedinthepro-ductionofmanufacturedgoodsandthewastegeneratedfromconsumption(afteruseintheeconomy).Exceptforpaper,thematerialimbalanceofhigh-incomecountriesispositiveand
orwaste.MISO2provideshigh-resolutiondatafor177countriesfrom1900to2016,withaspin-upperiodstartingin1820.AnotablefeatureofMISO2isitsconsistencywitheconomy-widematerialflowaccounting(ew-MFA),whichensuresasystematicmassbalancethroughouttheentirematerialcycle.
7F_7_8andF_8_9intheMISO2variabledefinition.
PAGE
8
morestable.Nevertheless,itmostlyshowsaslightdownwardtrend(afasterincreaseinwasteproductionthanproductiveneeds;itismorestableforglass).Thesituationfortherestoftheworldisentirelyopposite,withmaterialrequirementsrisingsharplyrelativetowasteproduced.
Figure3:MaterialImbalanceConsideringProducts’Life-Span
Notes:Thisfigurepresentsthetimeseriesofmaterialimbalanceembeddedinthedifferencesbetweenproductiveneedsandwastegenerationfromconsumption.Weconstructthedatasetfromtheeconomy-wide,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelofmaterialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)developedbyWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024).Toconstructthetimeseries,weuseMISO2-reporteddataonfinalmaterialproductionneeds(F78)minusend-of-lifewasteflows(F1011).Thatis,materialimbalancefromproductionandwastegenerationisF78–F1011andshowsthemismatchbetweenacountry’scontemporarymaterialneedsforitsproductionprocessesandtheavailablewastematerialsafterconsumption.Oncewecalculatethisvalueforeachcountry,weaggregatebycountrygroupbysummingoverallthecountriesinthatgroupandyear.
TheWasteMarketInteractingwithDomesticRecyclingPolicies
Inadditiontomaterialimbalanceandmarketforces,policiescanalsosignificantlyinfluencethewastemarket.TheEuropeanUnionexemplifiesthisphenomenon.Itsetspackagingrecyclingquotasformemberstates,whichtheycanfulfillthroughwasteexportforrecycling.8
WedemonstratethescaleofrecyclingexportsinrelationtotherecyclingperformanceofEuro-peancountries.Ouraimisnottodemonstrateacausallink,asitexistsbylaw.Ourobjectiveistoelucidatethephenomenon’sscaleandunderscoreitspolicyrelevance.WeusethepackagingrecyclingdataproducedbyEUROSTAT9andBACIforwasteexports.
8SeeDirective2018/852,whichamendedDirective1994/62/EC.Thesetargetsarealsodefinedatthepackagingmateriallevel:forinstance,50percentforplasticandaluminum,75percentforpaperandcardboard,and70percentforferrousmetals(Directive2018/852).
9Thisdatasetonlycoverspackagingwaste.Itexcludesotherwasteproductsofthesamematerials,suchas
homeappliances,clothing,andtools.
9
Since2018,membercountriesmustreporttheshareofrecyclingthatoccursoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.InTable1,wepresenttheaveragerecyclingsharesinthehomecountry,withintheEuropeanUnion,andoutsidetheEuropeanUnionfrom2018to2021.Onaverage,10–13percentoccursoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.
Table1:Avg.WasteGenerationandRecyclingSharesintheEuropeanUnion(2018–2021)
Generation(MT)
Share
Share
Share
Share
2018
3.03
61.98
59.34
32.04
13.19
2019
2.72
60.83
56.89
30.92
13.36
2020
3.06
61.40
58.26
27.46
13.83
2021
3.25
62.21
59.95
29.74
10.30
Avg.Waste
Recycling
LocalRecycling
EuropeanUnionRecycling
ForeignRecycling
Notes:ThistablepresentstheaverageannualvaluesacrossallEuropeanUnioncountriesforfivevariables:averagewastegenerationinmegatonnes,averagerecyclingrate,localrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclinghappeningdomestically),EuropeanUnionrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclingthatoccursinothermemberstates),andforeignrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclinghappeningincountriesoutsidetheEuropeanUnion).
However,dependingonthematerial,thissharewaslikelymuchhigherbeforetheChineseban.AccordingtoEuropeanParliament(2018),theEuropeanUnionusedtoexportapproximatelyhalfofitsplasticsdestinedforrecycling.Thiscouldhaveaccountedforupto50percentofEuropeancountries’plasticrecyclingrates,raisingconcernsabouttheirdependenceonforeignmarketsforwastemanagement.
Figure4presentstwosimpleexercisestoillustratetherelationshipbetweenrecyclingratesandwasteexportsamongEuropeanUnionmemberstates.Theleftpanelshowsascatterplotofrecyclingratesandtotalwasteexportsfrom2000to2021forthe15largesteconomiesintheEuropeanUnion,whichmandatesaminimumrecyclingrateof65percentforallpackagingwasteby2025.Thefigureincludesalinearfitforeachcountryinalevel-logspecification.Fourteenofthe15largesteconomiesshowapositiverelationshipbetweentheirrecyclingratesandwasteexports.10Atthetopright,weestimatetheelasticitybetweenthesetwofactorsusingasimplelevel-logmodelforeachcountry.11Thecoefficientsrangefrom26pp(Malta)to-6pp(Romania).Ofthe27countriesinthesample,23(85percent)showapositiveestimate,andonly4haveanegativecoefficient.Amongthe23countrieswithapositiveestimate,onlytwoarenotstatisticallydifferentfromzeroatthe10percentlevel,andnoneofthefourwithnegativecoefficientsisstatisticallysignificant.FourofthefivelargesteconomiesintheEuropeanUnion(France,Italy,Spain,andtheNetherlands)showapositiveandsignificantpointestimate.Inthebottomrightcorner,wepresenttheactualshareofrecyclingoutsidetheEuropeanUnionbetween2018and2022forcomparison.12Theratesareparticularlyhighforislandeconomies,
10TheonlyexceptionisGermany.Apossiblehypothesistotestisthatvariationsinlocalrecyclingorintra-
Europeanexportsbetterexplaintheincreaseinitsrecyclingrate.
11TheestimatedequationisRct=log(Wct)+ϵct.Rctistherecyclingrateforcountrycattimet,andWctisthetotalvolumeofwasteexportsoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.
12Thisinformationisunavailableforyearsbefore2018.However,themarketunderwentsignificantchangesafter
PAGE
10
whichalignwiththeirelasticities.
Figure4:EuropeanUnionRecyclingRatesandWasteExports
Notes:ThisfigurepresentstherelationshipbetweenEuropeanUnionrecyclingratesandwasteexports.PanelapresentsascatterplotoftherecyclingrateandthetotalwasteexportsoutsidetheEuropeanUnionbetween2000and2022forthe15largestEuropeanUnioneconomies.Foreachcountry,weindependentlymakealinearfitacrossallyearlyobservations.Panelbpresentsthepointestimatesofasimpleordinaryleastsquareslevel-logmodeloftherecyclingrateasafunctionofwasteexports.WeestimatethemodelindependentlyforeachEuropeanUnioncountryandplotpointestimatesand95percentconfidenceintervals.
TheTheoreticalModel
AutarkyinResources
Westartbyconsideringaneconomyinresourceautarkythatprohibitstradeinvirginresourcesandsecondarymaterialsor,alternatively,auniformglobaleconomy.
ThecountryhasasingleagentthatproducesgoodsfromauniquematerialwithweightQ¯,whosequantityisdeterminedexogenouslybyconsumerdemand.Inthepreviousperiod,theagentconsumedaquantityofgoodsC,whichisnowavailableasrecyclablewasteCw.Nonrecycledwasteisdisposedofwithdisutilityωandcostlyfortheuniqueagentofthecountry.Wedonotconsiderwastefromthepreviousperiodatdumpsitesforrecyclinginthecurrentperiod.ToproduceQ¯,theagentmustchoosebetweenusingthevirginnationalresourceRfromtheresourcereservoir(R¯)orrecyclingashareτofthenewlyavailablenationalwasteCw.
Intherecyclingvaluechain(collection,sorting,recycling),weassumethatcostconvexityexistsonlyinthecollectionandsortingprocesses,whichwemodelasthesamestep.Weconsider
Chinaimposedstrictrestrictionsonwasteimportsin2017.
PAGE
11
auniformdistributionofmaterialwastein[0,1],where0denotesthelocationoftherecyclingindustryandfirm,asinFleckingerandJoltreau(2020).Theagentstartsbycollectingthemostaccessiblewaste.Wastecollectionincursaunitcostγ.Thus,thecollectioncostscanbeexpressedasfollows:
r
τ
γ xdx=
0
γτ2
2
(1)
Costconvexityarisesbecausethelastcollectedwasteisoftenthemostexpensive,suchasfromremoteareasorhouseholdsthatresistsorting.13Anotherinterpretationisthatwastequalityvariesfrom0(pure)to1(impure);γrepresentsthesortingpremiumassociatedwithimpurity.Theunitcostofrecyclingthecollectedwasteisα,whichincludesrecyclingstandardsandnorms.
Weassumethatvirginresources(R)concentrateatpoint0andthatextractionoccursataconstantunitcostr.Extractioncostsincreaseovertime(Hotelling,1931),andcollectioncostsoccurperiodically.Inthismodel,weadoptastaticperspective.Hence,foragivenyear,wemodelextractioncostsasaconstantunitcost,allowingconvexityonlyinco
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 2025年中国煤炭考试题库及答案
- 高层建筑理论知识考核试题与答案
- 2025年临床医学检验类技士考试相关专业知识真题卷及答案
- 2.5 三大改造 说课稿 2025-2026学年统编版八年级历史下册
- 高中化学 专题2 营养均衡与人体健康 第四单元 造福人类健康的化学药物2说课稿 苏教版选修1
- 城市交通管理创新方案设计
- 整改会议记录标准模板下载
- 施工工程质量控制标准与案例
- 高校专业课程设置申请及优化建议
- 生物实验课程教学案例分享
- 2025年贵州省遵义市辅警考试真题及答案
- 国家事业单位招聘2025国家林业和草原局直属事业单位第二批招聘应届毕业生初试有关安排笔试历年参考题库附带答案详解
- GJB1406A-2021产品质量保证大纲要求
- 运动素质知到课后答案智慧树章节测试答案2025年春浙江大学
- 北师大九年级物理上册 (组装电路)简单电路 课件
- 2023年普通高中学业水平合格性考试音乐试卷
- 第八章世纪美国政治思想
- 起重机司机Q2(限桥式起重机)题库题库(1727道)
- 冠寓运营管理手册正式版
- GB/T 18839.2-2002涂覆涂料前钢材表面处理表面处理方法磨料喷射清理
- GB/T 12814-2002铁道车辆用车轴型式与基本尺寸
评论
0/150
提交评论