




免费预览已结束,剩余4页可下载查看
下载本文档
版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
济南大学毕业论文外文资料翻译毕业论文外文资料翻译题 目 西部农村新型农村养老保险参保 意愿的影响因素研究 以青海省乐都县八里桥村为例 学 院 政治与公共管理学院 专 业 劳动与社会保障 班 级 社保0803 班 学 生 赵继平 学 号 220080706103 指导教师 刘艳丽 二一二年三月二十五日 This section of articles selected from A Theory of the Consumption Function,P26-30.The writer is Friedman Milton. The assumptions that the first two correlations between the permanent and transitory components of income and of consumptionare zero seem very mild and highly plausible. Indeed, by themselves, they have little substantive content and can almost be as simply completing or translating the definitions of transitory and permanent components; the qualitative notion that the transitory component is intended to embody is of an accidental and transient addition to or subtraction from income, which is almost equivalent to saying an addition or subtraction that is not correlated with the rest of income. The merging of errors of measurement with transitory components contributes further to the plausibility that these correlations are zero. For a group of individuals, it is plausible to suppose that the absolute size of the transitory component varies with the size of the permanent component: that a given random event produces the same percentage rather than the same absolute increase or decrease in the incomes of units with different permanent components. This may make more convenient an alternative definition of transitory com- ponent that is suggested below; it is not, however, inconsistent with zero correlation. Zero correlation implies only that the average transitory componentthe algebraic average in which positive and negative. components offset one anotheris the same for all values of the permanent component. For example, suppose that the transitory component is equally likely to be plus or minus 10 percent of the permanent component. The average transitory component is then zero for all values of the permanent component, although the average absolute value, which disregards the sign of the components, is directly proportional to the permanent component. The plausibility of taking our definition of transitory components to imply a zero correlation for a group of consumer units depends somewhat on the criteria determining membership in the group. The clearest example is a classification of-units by the size of their measured income. For each such group, the correlation between permanent and transitory components is necessarily negative, since with a common measured income the permanent component can be relatively high only if the transitory component is relatively low, and conversely. The assumption that the third correlation in (3.3)between the transitory components of income and consumptionis zero is a much stronger assumption. It is primarily this assumption that introduces important substantive content into the hypothesis and makes it susceptible of contradiction by a wide range of phenomena capable of being observed. The ultimate test of its acceptability is of course whether such phenomena are in fact observed, and most of what follows is devoted to this question. It is hardly worth proceeding to such more refined tests, however, unless the assumption can pass or at least not fail miserablythe much cruder test of consistency with casual observation of ones self and ones neighbors, so some comments on the intuitive plausibility of the assumption are not out of order. The common notion that savings, or at least certain components of savings, are a residual speaks strongly for the plausibility of the assumption. For this notion implies that consumption is determined by rather long-term considerations, so that any transitory changes in income lead primarily to additions to assets or to the use of previously accumulated balances rather than to corresponding changes in consumption. Yet from another point of view, the assumption seems highly implausible. Will not a man who receives an unexpected windfall use at least some part of it in riotous living, i.e. in consumption expenditures? Would he be likely to add the whole of it to his wealth? The answer to these questions depends greatly on bow consumption is defined. The offhand affirmative answer reflects in large measure,I believe, an implicit definition of consumption in terms of purchases, including durable goods, rather than in terms of the value of services. If the latter definition is adopted, as seems highly desirable in applying the hypothesis to empirical datathough unfortunately I have been able to do so to only a limited extentmuch that one classifies off hand as consumption is reclassified as savings. Is not the windfall likely to be used for the purchase of durable goods? Or, to put it differently, is not the timing of the replacement of durable goods and of additions to the stock of such goods likely to some extent to be adjusted so as to coincide with windfalls? Two other consideration argue for the plausibility of the assumption that transitory components of income and consumption are uncorrelated.First, the above identification of a windfall with transitory income is not precise. Suppose, for example, inheritances are included .in a particular concept of measured income. Consider a consumer unit whose receipts remain unchanged over a succession of time periods except that it receives an inheritance in the final period. If the inheritance was expected to occur some time or other, it will already have been allowed for in permanent income; the transitory component of income is only the excess of the inheritance over this element of permanent income. There reason why the receipt of the inheritance should make consumption in the final period different from that of preceding periods, except through inability to borrow in advance on the strength of the inheritance. But this implies that the receipt of the inheritance changes w (the ratio of wealth to income) in (2.6); it is therefore already taken into account in the hypothesis. There is no essential difference if the inheritance is unexpected. The effect of the inheritance is then to increase the permanent income of the unit, and this will justify a higher consumption in the final period; again the transitory component is only the excess of the windfall over this element of permanent income, and it is no longer intuitively obvious that it should lead to an increase in current consumption.7 The second consideration is that just as there are instances in which one would expect a transitory increase in income to produce a transitory increase in consumption, so also there are instances in which, one would expect the reverse. The simplest example is when a transitory increase in income reduces opportunities for- consumption as when it is obtained by working longer hours or going to a backward country. Such negative and positive correlations will tend to offset one another. The preceding remarks abstract from errors of measurement. Yet, as noted, in any statistical analysis errors of measurement will in general be indissolubly merged with the correctly measured transitory components. The effect on the correlation between statistically recorded transitory components of income and consumption depends critically on how the statistical data are obtained. If income and consumption are measured independently, the. errors of estimate might be expected to be independent as well and therefore to contribute toward a small or zero observed correlation between transitory components of income and consumption. On the other hand, if consumption is estimated, as it frequently is, by measuring pendently savings and income and subtracting the former from the latter, then measured consumption and measured income have common errors of measurement. This tends toward a positive observed correlation between transitory components of income and consumption. The purpose of these remarks is not to demonstrate that a zero correlation is the only plausible assumptionneither evidence like that alluded to nor any other can justify such a conclusion. Its purpose is rather to show that common observation does not render it absurd to suppose that a hypothesis embodying a zero correlation can yield a fairly close approximation to observed consumer behavior. The assumption that the correlation between transitory components of income and consumption is zero could, of course, be replaced by the less restrictive assumption that it is a positive number between zero and unity, but this would greatly weaken the hypothesis and reduce its potential usefulness for predicting behavior. It seems highly undesirable to do so until and unless a significant contradiction arises between the stronger hypothesis and empirical evidence on consumer behavior. A particularly simple special case of the hypothesis arises if, in addition to (3.3), it is assumed that the mean transitory components of consumption and income are zero, or Where stands for the mean of the variable designated by its subscript. This assumption is eminently reasonable if the probability distribution in question is sufficiently comprehensive. In general, however, we shall want to use. conditional probability distributions, for example, the distribution of transitory components in a particular year, or for members of a particular group. In such cases, it will generally be undesirable to assume that (3.4) holds, just as for the single consumer unit viewed ex post it is undesirable to assume that the transitory components themselves are necessarily zero. It may be desirable or necessary to impose additional conditions on the probability distributions to facilitate the estimation of the parameters of the system from observed data. I shall, however, largely neglect the problem of statistical estimation, and so we need not go into such conditions. A more important qualification is that, for simplicity of exposition, equations (3.1) and (3.2) express the relation between observed income and its permanent and transitory components as additive. The form of the relation is important because it may affect the empirical validity of such specifications of the characteristics of the probability distributions as (3.3) and (3.4), as well as the validity of using specifications of other characteristics of the distribution that are convenient statistically. From this point of view, I conjecture that a multiplicative specification is preferable for income and. consumption data. If we let capital letters stand for the logarithms of the variables designated by the corresponding lower case letters, the equations defining the hypothesis then take the following alternative form: Many of the results that follow apply equally to both forms of the hypothesis, requiring only that the same symbol be interpreted in one case as an absolute value, in the other, as a logarithm. For any significant results for which this is not true, the logarithmic expressions are given in footnotes. 这篇文章选自第26至30页,作者弗里德曼。这个假设首先是两个变量间的关联永久的和暂时的收入与消费之间这看起来似乎是很合理的。事实上,就他们本身来说,很少有实质性的内容,几乎可以简单地完成或翻译的定义的临时性和永久性的成分;定性概念过渡部分是为了体现是一种偶然和短暂的加法或减法从收入,这几乎等同于说简单的加法或减法,不涉及其他收入。合并误差的测量与暂时性成分有助进一步证实这个零相关的可能性。对于一群个体,这是一个合理的假设即永久的和暂时的收入的绝对值:给定一个随机事件产生相同的百分比而不是相同的绝对增加或减少的收入与不同的永久组成部分单位。这可能使更方便的另一个定义的组成部分,是短暂的网站以下建议;它不是,但是,不符合零相关。零相关意味着只有平均短暂的组成部分代数平均在正面和负面的。部分抵消另一样的所有值的永久组成部分。例如,假设过渡部分是同样可能是加上或减去10%的永久组成部分。平均暂时的收入相对于永久收入组成部分几乎是零,虽然平均绝对价值很低,但我们不能无视该组成部分,是组成永久收入的很直接的比例。可信带定义性成分,意味着零相关的一组消费单位取决于标准确定的集团成员。最明显的例子是用他们的收入多少来一个分类别组。对于每一组,他们永久性和临时性收入之间的相关性必然是负的,因为与共同测量标准所得的永久性收入可以相对高,而暂时性的收入是相对低,反之亦然。假设这第三个相关(3.3)收入和消费之间的暂时部分其等于零是一个大胆的假设。它主要是在假设,介绍重要的实质性内容的假设,使它容易矛盾的各种现象可观察。最终检验其可接受性当然是这种现象其实是观察,最下面是专门讨论这个问题。这是不值得进行更精确的试验,然而,除非假设可以通过或至少不会很惨被推翻许多由自己和自己周围的人德尔观察等非精密的一致性检验,所以一些评论的可信的前提是假设是不失灵的。一般认为储蓄,或至少某些部分的储蓄,是一个“剩余”的强烈的可信的假设。这个概念意味着消费是由长期的考虑,使任何短暂的变化导致收入主要是补充资产或使用以前积累余额与其相应的消费变化。然而,从另一个角度来看,这似乎是非常难以置信的假设。将一名男子的一个意想不到的意外或至少部分在“放纵的生活,”也列为消费支出?他可能增加整个它自己的财富?这些问题的答案在很大程度上取决于“消费”的定义。所以在很大程度上反映了肯定的答案,我相信,一个隐含的定义消费采购方面,包括耐用消费品,而不是从服务的价值。如果是后者的定义,那么来自主观的信息更可信-尽管不幸的是我能够一直这样做只在有限的限度内-而更多的为消费重新分类就像储蓄所。不是因意外可能被用于购买耐用消费品?或者,换句话说,不定时更换耐用商品和增加的库存商品可能在一定程度上进行调整,以配合暴利?其他两种考虑认为作为可信的假设,短暂要素收入和消费是不相关的。首先,上述鉴定意外与暂时收入是不准确的。假设,举个例子,遗传是包括在内。在一个特定的概念,衡量收入。考虑一个消费单位的收入不变,在连续的时间内除,它
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 2025年四川省宜宾市事业单位工勤技能考试考试题库及参考答案
- 乐园为题作文以乐园为题作文7篇范文
- 柔术教学基本知识培训课件
- 枪支理论知识培训课件
- 2025浙江杭州萧山技师学院事业编制教师招录6人笔试模拟试题及答案解析
- 2025年湖南常德市市直机关公开遴选8名公务员考试参考题库附答案解析
- 2025广东省疾病预防控制中心招聘科研助理1人笔试参考题库附答案解析
- 2025福建莆田市湄洲湾北岸经济开发区国发投资有限公司后备干部招聘3人考试模拟试题及答案解析
- 2025四川九州光电子技术有限公司招聘质量助理工程师2人考试参考题库附答案解析
- 2025上海睿家社工服务社招聘项目社工笔试模拟试题及答案解析
- 2025 年西安市一年级语文秋季开学摸底考 - 基础卷及答案(人教版)
- 2025年秋新教科版三年级上册科学全册教案教学设计(新教材)
- 2025年云南省中考语文真题(附答案解析)
- 河南省洛阳市宜阳县2024-2025学年七年级下学期期末考试数学试卷(含答案)
- 第3讲 文言文内容概述题-据文比对判正误2026年高三语文第一轮总复习
- 房产抵押合同范本标准模板
- 针刺伤的预防与处理
- 印花税课件教学课件
- 2025年房地产开发商独家代理销售合作协议范本
- 2025年LNG加气站市场行业研究报告及未来发展趋势预测
- 2026创新设计高考总复习生物(人教版)-第十单元 第58课时 植物细胞工程
评论
0/150
提交评论