




已阅读5页,还剩9页未读, 继续免费阅读
版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
外文翻译译文1股票期权、当前的公司业绩和递延收益我们研究CEO股票期权的潜在不利影响。我们所抽取的上市公司样本的时间是1992-2001年。我们根据股票期权占CEO报酬总额的比例将观察值分为三组。我们根据实证文献认为股票期权的比例和公司当前经营业绩负相关。我们有证据显示,股权比例较高组,有明显异常的负相关的应计收入,而且表现为收益递延。1.研究设计和经验模型1.1研究设计我们研究1992-2001年期间上市公司CEO的股票期权。尽管其他管理者也有股权激励,但是本文主要研究CEO的股权激励。在我们的样本中,股票期权占了CEO报酬总额的大部分。我们以布莱克斯科尔斯模型测算出来的股票期权价值来测算股票期权占CEO总收入的份额。和Klassen、Ittner 、Mawani (2000)、Larcker (2003)一样,每家公司的期权比例,统一定义如下: SOPROP tt = Vt/ TCt _ 1这里的SOPROPt指股票期权占总报酬的比例,V指授予CEO的股票期权以布莱尔斯克斯模型测算的价值。TC指CEO每年的报酬总额。为了研究授予CEO期权是否和公司当前的业绩相关,我们根据股票期权的比例将观测值分为三组,我们首先根据SOPROP 按行业和年份对公司进行排序。第一组包括SOPROP值最低的三分之一的公司(低),第二组包括SOPROP值居中间的三分之一的公司(中等),第三组包括SOPROPt值最高的三分之一公司(高)。1.2实证模型为了研究股票期权和公司当前业绩之间的关系,我们对股票期权的比例和公司特定的业绩进行回归分析的同时控制变量。就如霍尔索森和拉克尔(1999年),我们使用资产收益率来衡量企业的业绩,具体地说,我们研究下面的关系:SOPROPit = 0 + 1 ROAit + 2 FINANCIAL_COSTit + 3 VARIABILITYit-1 +4 CHG_SALEit-1 + 5 SIZEit-1 + 6 GROWTHit-1 + 7 LEVERAGEit-1 +8 RETURN_1it + 9 RETURN_3it + eit 2SOPROP it =由方程定义的第t年的股票期权占公司i的CEO报酬总额的比例ROAit =公司i第t年的资产报酬率FINANCIAL_COSTit =如果在经营中前时期t公司i折旧收入的变化是积极的,指标变量等于1,否则为0VARIABILITYit-1 =公司i在期间t前60个月内的波动性CHG_SALEit-1 =公司i在t-2年和t-1年年销售额的差额SIZEit-1 =股东权益市场价值的自然对数GROWTHit-1 =公司i所有者权益的市场价值和账面价值的差额与市场价值的比例LEVERAGEit-1 =公司i在期间t的财务杠杆RETURN_1it =公司i在t时期期初的财务杠杆(负债对股本)RETURN_3it =公司i前三年的累积收益率2.实证分析2.1样本选择和描述统计我们获取从1992-2001年CEO的报酬的数据(我们从2002年的Execucomp数据库中获取1999-2001年报酬的数据)。该数据包含了最高五位CEO的报酬。我们收集了所有公司的CEO的报酬的数据。除了报酬总额,该数据库提供了CEO收入的详细组成部分,包括以布莱尔斯科尔斯模型估值的股票期权、工资和奖金(除了报酬总额,该数据库还提供布莱尔斯克斯模型确定的股票期权、工资总额、奖金的详细组成)。原始的样本包括2502家公司一共有14013个符合的观测值。我们从原始数据中剔除了金融机构(1852个观测值)和没有给CEO股权激励的(3442个观察值)以及CEO的报酬低于1百万(1757个观察值)的公司。因为需要计算股票收益率的波动性,我们同样剔除了CRSP数据库中最近60个月没有股票收益率的1013个观察值。最后,我们还剔除了额外的缺少数据的857个观察值。这样我们得到一个有5092个观测值和1353个公司的样本。为了研究股票期权和当前非正常的应计项目,我们需要估算随意的应计项目。因此我们使用道琼斯模型进行这些测试,需要的会计数据取自Compustat数据库。我们的样本中所包含的公司是盈利的(平均资产回报率为5.01%)。CEO的平均报酬高于500万,其中47%为股票期权,40%为现金。对于股票期权所占比例较低的组,股票期权的平均比例是22%,现金的比例是53%。相反的,股票期权比例较高的组,股票期权的比例几乎占了报酬总额的四分之三,而现金只占了报酬总额的23%。对于每一组来说,资产的报酬率都是正数,但是股票期权比例高的那组的报酬率最低。三组的平均数来说是正增长,但是杠杆比例似乎与股票期权的比例负相关。平均来说,有较高期权比例的公司与上年和过去的三年比有更高的回报率,其证券市场的波动率也更大。3.公司业绩和股票期权的比例用模型2来测试股票期权的比例是否和公司的业绩呈正相关的关系。我们根据股票期权的比例将数据划分为三组。我们首先根据SOPROP按行业按年进行排序。一组包括SOPROPt值最低的三分之一的公司(低),第二组包括SOPROPt值居中间三分之一的公司(中等),第三组包括SOPROPt值最高的三分之一公司(高)。用托宾Q测试表明SOPROPt值最高的那组和SOPROPt值最低的那组呈在显著的差异(在1%的水平),从而拒绝了分布均匀的假设。因此它是在适当平局模型2的基础上单独的回归。正如表1列A所示,股票期权的比例较低的公司,即在10%水平时,它对当时公司的业绩产生积极显著的影响。股票期权的比例排在中间的公司,如列B所示,它对当时公司的业绩产生负的但不显著的影响。然而在股票期权的比例高的公司,即1%水平,如列C所示,它对当时公司的业绩产生显著的负面的影响。4.总结在本文中,我们选取了1992-2001年的上市公司作为样本,然后根据股票期权的比例对公司进行分类。股票期权比例高的企业,股票期权比例高的企业,即使控制了与股票期权相关的其他已知变量,我们得出股票期权比例与公司同期业绩负相关。股票期权比例低的企业,我们观察到同期的经营业绩与股票期权的比例呈正相关。当股票期权占经营者报酬总额的比例较高时,经营者的报酬在未来业绩中急剧增加。这种公司中的经营者意识到潜在的巨大收益,有动机将当前的收入和收益推迟到未来期间确认。我们的结论和猜测相一致。总得来说,本研究认为对CEO授予过度的股权激励具有负面影响。这种行为会对现任股东的财富产生不利影响。作者:K.柯克达瑞/M.罗伯特国籍:加拿大出处:国际管理期刊,第26卷第1期,2009年4月,第26-31页原文1Stock Option Grants, Current Operating Performanceand Deferral of EarningsWe examine a potential negative consequence of stock option grants to the ChiefExecutive Officer (CEO). Using a large sample of public firms spanning the period1992-2001, we classify firm-year observations into three groups based on the stockoption proportion of total compensation to the CEO. We empirically document a negativerelation between stock option proportion and contemporaneous operating performance.We provide evidence of earnings deferral manifested by significantly negative abnormalaccruals for the group with high proportion of stock options.2. Research Design and Empirical Model2.1 Research DesignWe examine CEO stock options grants of public corporations during 1992-2001. While stock options grants are used to compensate other employees as well as CEOs, this study focuses only on CEOs. In our sample, stock options constitute a larger proportion of CEOs total compensation compared to other employees. We measure the stock option proportion as the ratio of Black-Scholes value of the total options granted to the CEO in a particular year to the total compensation granted to the CEO that year. Consistent with Klassen and Mawani (2000) and Ittner, Lambert and Larcker (2003), stock option proportion for each firm-year is defined as follows:V SOPROP t t = Vt/ TCt _ 1where SOPROP is the proportion of total compensation that consists of stock options; V is the Black-Scholes value of options granted to the CEO; and TC is the total compensation paid to the CEO in the year.In order to examine whether the granting of CEO stock options is associated with a firmscurrent operating performance, we classify firm-year observations into three groupsbased on the proportion of stock options. We first rank firms based on their SOPROPby year and by industry. The first group comprises the bottom one third of firms (low),the second group the middle one third (medium) and the third group includes firms withtop one third (high) proportion of stock options. 3.2 Empirical ModelTo examine the association between current performance and stock options, we regressthe proportion of stock options on firm-specific performance as well as control variablesidentified in prior studies as determinants of stock option grants. As in Core, Holthausen and Larcker (1999), we use the accounting return on assets (ROA) as the proxy for firm performance. Specifically, we examine the following relation:SOPROPit = 0 + 1 ROAit + 2 FINANCIAL_COSTit + 3 VARIABILITYit-1 +4 CHG_SALEit-1 + 5 SIZEit-1 + 6 GROWTHit-1 + 7 LEVERAGEit-1 +8 RETURN_1it + 9 RETURN_3it + eit 2SOPROP it = the proportion of the CEOs total compensation of firm i that is composed on stock options in year t as defined by equation 1. The stock options are valued using the Black & Scholes option pricing formula;ROAit = the return on assets of firm i on year t;FINANCIAL_COSTit = an indicator variable that equals 1 if the change in operatingincome before depreciation for firm i in period t is positive andis 0 otherwise;VARIABILITYit-1 = variability of firm is stock return for the period of 60 months prior to year t;CHG_SALEit-1 = change in the annual sales of firm i between period t-2 and t-1;SIZEit-1 = natural log of the beginning market value of equity;GROWTHit-1 = ratio of the beginning book value of equity of firm i over the beginning market value of equity;LEVERAGEit-1 = financial leverage (liabilities over equity) of firm i at the beginning of period t;RETURN_1it = stock returns of firm i over prior one year; andRETURN_3it = cumulative stock returns of firm i over prior three years.3. Empirical Analyses3.1 Sample3. Empirical Analyses3.1 Sample Selection and Descriptive Statistics We obtain compensation data from 2002 Execucomp database for the period 1992 to 2001. The database contains the information regarding the compensation of the top five executives. We collect compensation data for all firms for which CEO is identified. In addition to the total compensation, the database provides a detailed composition including the Black & Scholes value stock options, the amount of salary and the bonuses.The initial sample consists of 2,502 companies and a corresponding total of 14,013 firm-year observations.We exclude financial institutions (1,852 observations), CEOs that are not awarded stock options (3,442 observations) and firms providing compensation lower than 1 million dollars (1,757 observations) from the initial sample. We also eliminate 1,013 observations that do not have 60 months of stock return in CRSP, required to compute the stock return volatility. Finally, we eliminate an additional 857 observations due to missing data. This gives us a sample of 5,092 firm-year observations for 1,353 companies. To investigate our question relating to the association between stock option compensation and current abnormal accruals, we need to estimate the discretionary accruals. We employ the modified Jones model for this purpose. Accounting data necessary to conduct these tests are obtained from Compustat. Firms included in our sample are profitable (average return on asset of 5.01%). The average value of CEO compensation is over 5 million dollars and stock options represent 47% of the value of total compensation for our sample firms, compare to 40% for the cash component. For the group of firms with low proportions of stock options, stock options, account on average, for 22% of the total compensation, while the cash component represents 53%. Conversely, stock options represent almost three quarter of total compensation of the group of firms with a high proportions of stock options, while the cash component is 23% of total compensation. For each group of firms, the average return on assets is positive but it is lower for the group of firms with a high proportion of stock options. All three groups experience positive growth, on average, and the leverage ratio seems to be negatively correlated to the proportion of stock options. On average, firms with a high proportion of stock options have experienced a higher return on their stock over the last year and the last three years. The volatility of stock return is also higher for firms with a high proportionof stock options.4. ConclusionIn this paper, we employ a sample of public firms spanning the period 1992-2001, and classify firm-year observations based on the proportion of stock options. For firms with a high proportion of stock options, we document a negative association between proportion of stock options and contemporaneous operating performance, even after controlling for other known variables associated with stock option grants. For firms with a low proportion of stock options, we observe a positive association between contemporaneous operating performance and proportion of stock options. When stock options grants constitute a large proportion of total compensation, manager payoffs increase steeply at higher levels of future performance (i.e., the compensation is convex).Managers of such firms, recognizing the potential for large payoffs, have incentives to postpone revenues and earnings from the current to future periods. Our results are consistent with this conjecture. Overall, this study identifies a potential negative consequence of granting excessivelevels of stock options to CEOs. Such behavior can negatively affect the wealth of incumbent shareholders.Author:K. KiridaranNationality: Canada/ CanadaOriginate from: International Journal of Management,Vol.26 No.1,April 2009,P26-31译文2组织为留住员工的激励理论以及它们的应用的研究为什么必须要留住关键性的雇员? Fitz-enz(1997年)提出,公司每失去10个管理上和专业上的员工就会损失100美元。算上直接成本和间接成本,避免雇员流失的总成本,是其一年工资和福利的最小量,或两年的薪酬和福利的最大值。对于一个组织来说,失去任何一个关键的雇员都会产生严重的经济影响,特别是考虑到随雇员离去而丧失的知识。这些知识是可以用来满足顾客的需要和期望的。知识的管理是创造、捕捉的过程以及知识来提高组织绩效的进程。 此外,Toracco(2000年)指出,虽然现在知识已经被认为是一个组织最宝贵的资产,但是,大多数组织缺乏必要的保留和利用知识价值的配套制度。组织不能只站在消极的立场上去希望人们在这个组织内能够得到和利用那些已知的、可以接近的知识。相反,组织应该以寻求维持竞争优势为目的,迅速发展能充分利用知识价值的系统(Robinson & Stern, 1997; Stewart, 1997).。因此,这很容易看到失去了宝贵的员工的知识的巨大影响。人力资本和知识管理的概念是,人们拥有的技能,经验和知识,因此对组织具有经济价值。这些技能,知识和经验代表了资本,因为它们提高了生产率(Snell and Dean, 1992)。人力资本理论假定某些劳动力更有生产力仅仅是因为越来越多的资源投资在劳动力培训上,相当于一台机器投入了更多的资源来提高生产率ller, 1982)。人力资本理论的一条基本原则是,如同任何商业投资,“投资技能建设将更加有利可图,更有可能将要持续较长的时期,从而获得投资回报” (Mueller, 1982, p. 94)。此外,留住对于实现充分的投资回报是非常重要的。人力资本理论还认为员工在一个组织的服务长度可以作为与职业相关的知识或能力的代表。一个人对与工作有关的知识或能力的了解,影响该人的工资,推销自己和工作的类型(Becker,1975; Hulin & Smith,1967; Katz,1978)。在一个组织里,关于工龄的理解可以与乌尔里希(1998)定义的智力资本承诺的组成部分联系起来。他的定义很简单“技能通过承诺而增加” (p. 125),智力资本的重要性等于知识,技能和每一个人在组织中的属性乘以他们愿意努力工作。在未来几年,个人对组织的承诺将得到更重要的承认,以及该组织需要创建一个有人会愿意留下来的环境(Harris, 2000)。组织将需要或创建一个智力资本环境下,知识的传播的发生将遍及整个组织,或继续通过工龄发展失去重要的个人知识。许多人认为这些深奥的知识将有助于满足客户的需求和期望,并在全球经济组织相互竞争的今天,创建和维持竞争优势。作者:苏尼尔国籍:美国出处:美国商业学术期刊,2004年9月,第52-59页原文2A Review of Employee Motivation Theories and their Implicationsfor Employee Retention within OrganizationsWhy is it Necessary to Retain Critical Employees?Fitz-enz (1997) stated that the average company loses approximately $1 million with every 10 managerial and professional employees who leave the organization. Combined with direct and indirect costs, the total cost of an exempt employee turnover is a minimum of one years pay and benefits, or a maximum of two years pay and benefits. There is significant economic impact with an organization losing any of its critical employees, especially given the knowledge that is lost with the employees departure. This is the knowledge that is used to meet the needs knowledge to enhance organizational performance (Bassi, 1997). Furthermore, Toracco (2000) stated that although knowledge is now recognized as one of an organizations most valuable assets most organizations lack the supportive systems required to retain and leverage the value of knowledge. Organizations cannot afford to take a passive stance toward knowledge management in the hopes that people are acquiring and using knowledge, and that sources of knowledge are known and accessed throughout the organization. Instead, organizations seeking to sustain competitive advantage have moved quickly to develop systems to leverage the value of knowledge for this purpose (Robinson & Stern, 1997; Stewart, 1997). Thus, it is easy to see the dramatic effect of losing employees who have valuable knowledge. The concept of human capital and knowledge management is that people possess skills, experience and knowledge, and therefore have economic value to organizations. These skills, knowledge and experience represent capital because they enhance productivity (Snell and Dean, 1992). Human capital theory postulates that some labor is more productive than other labor simply because more resources have been invested into the training of that labor, in the same manner that a machine that has had more resources invested into it is apt to be more productive (Mueller, 1982). One of the basic tenets of human capital theory is that, like any business investment, an “investment in skill-building would be more profitable and more likely to be undertaken the longer the period over which returns from the investment can accrue” (Mueller, 1982, p. 94). Again, employee retention is important in realizing a full return on investment. Human capital theory includes the length of service in the organization as aproxy for job relevant knowledge or ability. A persons job relevant knowledge or ability influences that persons wage, promotional opportunity and/or type of job (Becker, 1975; Hulin & Smith, 1967; Katz, 1978). The understanding of length of service in an organization relates back to Ulrichs (1998) component of commitment in his definition of intellectual capital. His definition was simply “competence multiplied by commitment” (p. 125), meaning intellectual capital equals the knowledge, skills, and attributes of each individual within an organization multiplied by their willingness to work hard. It will become significantly more important in the years ahead to recognize the commitment of individuals to an organization, as well as the organizations need to create an environment in which one would be willing to stay (Harris, 2000). Organizations will need to either create an intellectual capital environment where the transmission of knowledge takes place throughout the structure, or continue to lose important individual knowledge that has been developed through the length of service. This deep knowledge is what many believe will help to meet the needs and expectations of the customers and to create and sustain a competitive advantage within the global economy in which organizations are competing in today.Author: Sunil RamlallNationnality:AmericaOriginate from:The Journal of American Academy of Business,September 2004,P52-5910/30 17:12 C620轴拨杆的工艺规程及钻2-16孔的钻床夹具设计09/21 13:39 CA6140车床拨叉零件的机械加工工艺规程及夹具设计83100308/30 15:37 CPU风扇后盖的注塑模具设计09/20 16:19 GDC956160工业对辊成型机设计08/30 15:45 LS型螺旋输送机的设计10/07 23:43 LS型螺旋输送机设计09/20 16:23 P-90B型耙斗式装载机设计09/08 20:17 PE10自行车无级变速器设计10/07 09:23 话机机座下壳模具的设计与制造09/08 20:20 T108吨自卸车拐轴的断裂原因分析及优化设计09/21 13:39 X-Y型数控铣床工作台的设计09/08 20:25 YD5141SYZ后压缩式垃圾车的上装箱体设计10/07 09:20 ZH1115W柴油机气缸体三面粗镗组合机床总体及左主轴箱设计09/21 15:34 ZXT-06型多臂机凸轮轴加工工艺及工装设计10/30 16:04 三孔连杆零件的工艺规程及钻35H6孔的夹具设计08/30 17:57 三层货运电梯曳引机及传动系统设计10/29 14:08 上盖的工工艺规程及钻6-4.5孔的夹具设计10/04 13:45 五吨单头液压放料机的设计10/04 13:44 五吨单头液压放料机设计09/09 23:4
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 2025年金融机构员工保密协议规范
- 2025年福州股权合伙人策划退出协议书
- 2025年自动化技术应用合作协议
- 2025年校园有线网络覆盖委托施工协议
- 2025年临时用电事故应急预案与处理协议
- 2025年联合图书策划出版协作协议
- 2025年企业保密协议标准化策划范本
- 2025年室内设计装修合作协议书
- 高模量玻璃纤维布项目投资风险评估报告
- 新媒体时代健美操推广模式的创新
- 2025年高中化学学业水平合格性考试模拟试卷试题(含答案)
- 水利安全风险防控“六项机制”与安全生产培训
- AI在知识库领域的应用
- 国开(陕西)2024年秋《社会调查》形考作业1-4答案
- DZ/T 0430-2023 固体矿产资源储量核实报告编写规范(正式版)
- 2024年燕舞集团限公司公开招聘高频考题难、易错点模拟试题(共500题)附带答案详解
- 人工智能导论智慧树知到课后章节答案2023年下哈尔滨工程大学
- YY∕T 1849-2022 重组胶原蛋白
- 各省份发展水平的主成分及聚类分析
- 丽声北极星自然拼读绘本第六级Mark at the Park 课件
- (高清版)《预应力筋用锚具、夹具和连接器应用技术规程》JGJ85-2010
评论
0/150
提交评论