




已阅读5页,还剩41页未读, 继续免费阅读
版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
How Much Ownership, Institutions and Competition Matter for Patent Premium in Weak Intellectual Property Rights Protection MarketsAbstractThe weak intellectual property rights (IPR) protection in emerging markets pose a critical challenge for foreign firms attempting to appropriate returns from innovation in these markets. In this study, we investigate whether and when foreign firms in emerging markets obtain patent premium, defined as incremental productivity gains from a firms patents compared with its productivity had the firm not owned any patents. Drawing on complementary theoretical insights from institutional logic and liability of foreignness, we predict and analyze how firm ownership, institutional development, and competition intensity affect patent premium. Our empirical analysis of a ten-year period of 32,901 firms in Chinas high-tech industries wherein foreign firms are actively competing answered a puzzle: Foreign firms do obtain patent premium despite the weak IPR protection in the country. Among foreign firms, the level of patent premium is significantly lower for international joint ventures than for wholly owned foreign subsidiaries. We also find that foreign firms obtain lower patent premium than domestic firms, particularly in institutional weak regions within the country. However, patent premium growth due to improved institutional development is stronger for foreign firms than for domestic firms, whereas patent premium diminution due to heightened competition is stronger for domestic firms than for foreign firms. These suggest that foreign firms, comparing with local firms, are more prone to institutional improvement but less susceptible to industry competition concerning reaping rewards from patents and innovation. Keywords: Patent premium, IPR, innovation, institutions, emerging economyINTRODUCTIONIt has been a big paradoxical question to both scholars and executives alike for some time: Can innovation and patents pay off for foreign firms competing in large emerging markets where market opportunities are enormous yet intellectual property rights (IPR) protection is rather limited? The last decade has witnessed a surge of innovation activities of multinational companies (MNCs) in emerging markets (Qu, Huang, Zhang, & Zhao, 2013, Thursby & Thursby, 2006, Zhao, 2006). However, the weak IPR protection there pose a critical challenge for MNCs attempting to appropriate returns from patenting activities. The appropriation literature asserts that patenting may not be viable in countries where law enforcement for IPR is weak (Al-Aali & Teece, 2013) because the effectiveness of patenting primarily depends on the quality of national law system and institutional environment in which firms operate (Schankerman, 1998, Somaya, 2012). In such cases, innovators must count on other appropriation mechanisms, such as secrecy, control of complementary resources, or taking an advantage of lead time (“first to market”) to capture value from innovations (Al-Aali & Teece, 2013). Nevertheless, patent applications in emerging markets have been growing steadily in recent decades (Keupp, Friesike, & von Zedtwitz, 2012, Li, 2012). Patent statistics reveals that the number of invention patent applications received by the State Intellectual Property Office of China (SIPO), for instance, increased from 63,000 in 2001 to 1.3 million in 2016, producing a staggering 21-fold growth. Domestic and foreign applications for invention patents in the nation have both been growing at an annual average rate of 21% in the period of 1986-2015 (Hu, 2010, Hu & Jefferson, 2009), with the fact that China surpassed the US since 2011 becoming the worlds biggest country in receiving patent applications.This phenomenon is striking considering the weak institutional environment and IPR protection in these economies, which presumably leads to weak incentives to patent (Hu & Jefferson, 2009). The paradox has prompted researchers to investigate the conditions that are motivating the rapid growth of patenting in these countries (Hu, 2010, Hu & Jefferson, 2009, Keupp, Friesike, & von Zedtwitz, 2012, Li, 2012). It has been recognized that market size and economic advancement may offset some disincentives of patenting activities caused by weak IPR protection (Huang & Jacob, 2014), and governmental support (e.g., better financial and policy treatment) for innovation may foster firm-level patenting activities despite the existence of patent infringement (Huang, 2017, Li, 2012). Others also suggest that improved physical infrastructure and geographic clusters for innovation are conduits of patenting undertaking (Hu & Mathews, 2005, Porter & Stern, 2001). Despite these great efforts, nevertheless, it remains unanswered whether and when patents are valuable for foreign firms in large emerging markets characterized with weak IPR protection. Combining insights from institutional logic and liability of foreignness, we aim to understand how much patenting is valuable for foreign firms in such an important context. We denote the value of patents by patent premium, which generally refers to increment to the value of technological innovations realized by patenting them (Arora, Ceccagnoli, & Cohen, 2008)Arora, 2008, R&D and the Patent Premium;Arora, 2008, R&D and the Patent PremiumArora, 2008, R&D and the Patent Premium;Jensen, 2011, Estimating the patent premium: Evidence from the Australian Inventor Survey, and specifically in this study connotes to incremental productivity gains from a firms patents compared with its productivity had the firm not owned any patents. We propose that firm ownership (foreign vs. domestic; wholly owned foreign subsidiaries (WOS) vs. international joint ventures (IJV) can shape the firms patent premium, and in particular, the effect of institutional development and competition intensity on patent premium is conditional upon firm ownership (foreign vs. domestic) due to liabilities of foreignness. The ideal method to estimate patent premium is to compare productivity of a patent-owning firm with its productivity had the firm not owned any patents, but the productivity of a patent-owing firm had it not owned any patents is hard to observe. In order to provide robust evidence, we tackle this challenge by employing a matching and difference-in-difference method and using a large dataset of high-technology (high-tech) companies competing in China, the largest emerging market that features well with market opportunities, weak IPR protection, institutional change, and intensified competition in most sectors.Our longitudinal analysis of a ten-year period of 32,901 firms in Chinas high-tech industries (in which foreign firms actively operate) through our compiling and matching the data from Chinas National Bureau of Statistics Annual Survey of Industrial Enterprises with the patent data from SIPO offers some very interesting and important insights. First, we find a significantly positive patent premium among foreign firms in China. However, this positive premium is not equally distributed across foreign firms of different ownership types. We find that WOS gained higher patent premium than IJV. Second, domestic firms obtained higher patent premium than foreign firms, thus validating the existence of liability of foreignness in this regard. Third, patent premium growth due to improved institutional development is stronger for foreign firms than for domestic firms, whereas patent premium diminution due to heightened competition is stronger for domestic firms than for foreign firms. These suggest that foreign firms, compared with local firms, are more prone to institutional improvement but less susceptible to industry competition concerning reaping rewards from patents and innovation.These results, detailed later, provide both theoretical and practical insights. It, for instance, reminds that while liability of foreignness does exist regarding patent premium or innovation gains in more general, foreign firms can benefit from their core capabilities in alleviating such liabilities so that patent premium can grow more for foreign than for local firms in regions (geographically) where institutions are better developed. Or, patent premium will decrease less for foreign firms than for local cohorts in sectors (industrially) where competition intensity is higher. This study also exhibits strong evidence on institutional complexity in general and institutional incompatibility in particular, suggesting that subnational variance in institutional conditions exerts an important impact on patenting activities and rewards. An understanding of institutional logic is fuller if we unite the institutional void logic (weak IPR protection) and the institutional complexity logic (institutional fragility and incompatibility across different locations with a country) in analyzing both foreign and local firms. While competition can create more value to societal well-being in emerging markets (Devarajan & Rodrik, 1989), it does squeeze patent premium, more so for domestic firms than for foreign counterparts.THEORETICAL DEVELOPMENTPatenting under Weak IPR Protection: Theoretic LogicPatenting has long been recognized as a differentiating mechanism, providing owners with the right to exclude others from using the invention for a limited period (Mansfield, 1986, Ziedonis, 2004). The exclusionary power of patent rights can bring market power (Bessen, 2009) and allow firms to pursue additional profit opportunities and competitive advantage (Gambardella, 2013, Somaya, 2012). A firm holding patent rights can exercise market power by raising the prices it charges for its own products or services above the level at which they would charge in a competitive market. Patent holders can also bolster market power through enforcement of patent rights, which entails the use or threatened use of litigation to stop infringers from using patented inventions. These holders can further develop a carefully crafted portfolio of related patents to impede imitation, deter competition, and defend against patent infringement (Fisher Iii & Oberholzer-Gee, 2013, Reitzig, 2004, Whittington, Owen-Smith, & Powell, 2009). Firms can additionally appropriate patent returns through licensing or selling patent rights. These transactions can be beneficial or even bring strategic advantage for the patent owners (Fisher Iii & Oberholzer-Gee, 2013, Somaya, 2012). Finally, firms can enhance the value of their patent rights through standard setting and technological collaboration. When a firms patents are included in a technology standard, these patents are more likely to be demanded and licensed (Joshi & Nerkar, 2011). Moreover, the inclusion of patents in standards-based patent pools can increase subsequent innovations that build on them (Rysman & Simcoe, 2008), which may propel the patented technologies toward becoming a dominant design in the industry (Teece, 1986).While the above logic generally applies to firms in every country, actual returns or benefits of patenting activities will significantly vary depending on institutional and market environments. Perhaps, there is no country that brings in such complexity and paradox for firms to deal with patenting activities as larger emerging economies like China and India. Markets are huge yet IPR protection remains weak. Albeit some of these governments have been making efforts in protecting patent rights, especially after joining the World Trade Organization (WTO), legal enforcement of IPR protection is impeded by a plentitude of perilous issues such as public empathy of copycatting (Luo, Sun, & Wang, 2011), weak judiciary and administrative systems (especially local levels) in IPR (Bosworth & Yang, 2000, Wang, 2004), business and public sector corruption (Kshetri, 2009, Liu, 2006), and political and institutional instability (Lieberthal & Lieberthal, 2003). Such institutional voids or hardships relating to patenting activities are further exacerbated by lack of institutional transparency and limited and often selective enforcement of IPR law (Khanna & Palepu, 2013, Ostergard, 2000, Oxley, 1999). This makes it difficult to appropriate returns from innovation through patent protection (Al-Aali & Teece, 2013, Schankerman, 1998, Teece, 1986). We approach this paradox from the institutional logic, complemented with the liability of foreignness logic. The institutional logic we develop originates from works that integrate institutional theory (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983, Scott, 1987) and strategic choice that hinges in part on a firms dependence on external institutions that control critical resources (Oliver, 1991, Peng, 2003, Tolbert, 1985). This institution-based view of strategy, and Olivers strategic response logic to institutional processes in particular (Oliver, 1991, Oliver, 1997), holds that institutional forces enact a strong effect on organizations, even more so during institutional change (Peng, 2003, Peng & Zhou, 2005) but this effect is not equal to every organization in the said institutional setting due to three idiosyncrasies - one in varying dependence on external institutions that maintain power stemming from resource control (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978), second in varying strategic intent to exploit opportunities during institutional change (Hitt, Ahlstrom, Dacin, Levitas, & Svobodina, 2004), and third in varying policy treatments or capabilities in dealing with institutional dynamics (Hillman & Keim, 1995). Grounding on such logic, we argue that institutional hazards, such as weak IPR protection, may hinder patenting activities but competitive opportunities and values through patenting in a large emerging economy characterized with vast market demand can be adequate enough to offset this hindering effect. This will be particularly true when firms are located in a more institutionally developed region (i.e., weaker institutional effect) within a large market, or when opportunities in the sector in which the firm competes are more abundant (i.e., lower industrial competition). The above premise can be further delineated complementarily by liabilities of foreignness logic (Zaheer, 1995, Zaheer & Mosakowski, 1997). We expect that foreign firms patenting rewards will be lower than local firms due to liability of foreignness, which is, in this case, manifested in extra difficulties, challenges and costs in responding to weak IPR protection. This suggests that foreign firms are deemed to benefit less from patenting gains in weak IPR protection markets than local firms. This prediction can be even stronger when the overall institutional development is poorer in a firm-located sub-region within the country.We study patenting gains by patent premium, defined as incremental productivity gains from a firms patents compared with its productivity had the firm not owned any patents, in the context of large emerging markets that are characterized with fast-growing economy, sheer market size and vast market opportunities yet featured too with weak IPR protection at the national level, dissimilar institutional development at the subnational (regional) level, and rapidly intensified competition at the industry level. A patent is a document issued upon application by a government office, which describes an invention which may relate to a product or a process, and creates a legal situation in which the patented invention can normally only be exploited (manufactured, used, sold, imported) with the authorization of the owner of the patent. As detailed below, we first probe whether or not there exists patent premium for foreign firms in a large emerging market and then hypothesize how such premium is influenced by ownership types of foreign firms (IJV versus WOS). Then we compare patent premium between foreign and domestic firms, building in part on the logic of liabilities of foreignness. What follows then is our explanation on how institutional development in a sub-region where the firm is located and competition intensity in an industry in which the firm competes affect patent premium for foreign and domestic firms, respectively. Institutional development is the degree to which market support economic activities, including protection of IPR, regulatory and legislative supportiveness to business, and development of non-stated-owned enterprises, product and factor market and market intermediaries and legal systems, among others (Meyer & Nguyen, 2005). We chose high-tech industries as our specific analytical setting as it is the one in which foreign firms have been actively competing with local firms yet it is the one that is highly susceptible to IPR infringement. Patent Premium and Ownership Type Despite the weak IPR protections in large emerging markets (e.g., China, Brazil and India), the last decade has witnessed a surge of technological innovation in these economies (Lewin, Massini, & Peeters, 2009, Qu, Huang, Zhang, & Zhao, 2013, Sartor & Beamish, 2014). One central driver of the innovation surge in these markets is that they present vast market opportunities and huge demand (Orr & Roth, 2012, Wale, Dvorak, Kaza, Santhanam, & Yang, 2012), yet the market environment there is highly competitive and rapidly changing (Chen, Liu, & Tjosvold, 2005, Yam, Guan, Pun, & Tang, 2004). The other crucial driver is that emerging markets such as China and India possess a growing pool of skilled engineers and scientists at a fairly low cost whereas there is an emerging shortage of science and engineering talent in developed markets (Lewin, Massini, & Peeters, 2009, Orr & Roth, 2012, Zhao, 2006). As MNCs broaden their innovation activities in these large emerging markets, the risk of exposing their technologies to potential imitation and misappropriation increases and the need to protect their technological innovation rises. Among various methods to pro
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 儿童与青少年艺术教育的创新方法-洞察及研究
- 教育机构2025年线上招生招生渠道拓展与招生市场分析报告
- 2025年生态湿地公园水生态修复技术创新可行性分析
- 2025-2030药食同源饮品行业趋势分析及市场教育与资本介入机会研究报告
- 无碳纸显色剂创新创业项目商业计划书
- 家庭维护材料创新创业项目商业计划书
- 森林认证与可持续管理咨询创新创业项目商业计划书
- 水果初加工产业化示范创新创业项目商业计划书
- 水稻种植绿色发展创新创业项目商业计划书
- 北京安全员a证练习题库及答案解析
- 【音乐】七年级开学第一课音乐课件
- 防火防烟分区检查
- 人工智能在智能体育中的应用
- 服装季度分析报告
- 农产品营销的渠道策略讲义
- 工程总承包(EPC)模式市场应用现状
- 食品安全管理制度小卖部
- 初中语文阅读ppt课件ppt
- 学生上下学交通方式台账
- 建筑垃圾处理及清运方案
- 路边停车经营管理方案
评论
0/150
提交评论