




版权说明:本文档由用户提供并上传,收益归属内容提供方,若内容存在侵权,请进行举报或认领
文档简介
1、代理成本和股权结构外文翻译 外文翻译agency costs and ownership structure material source: the journal of finance ?vol.lv,no.1?february 2000 page83-87 author: james s. ang, rebel a. cole, and james wuh lin i. agency costs among small businesses when compared to publicly traded firms, small businesses come closest to t
2、he type of firms depicted in the stylized theoretical model of agency costs developed by jensen and meckling1976. at one extreme of ownership and management structures are firms whose managers own 100 percent of the firm. these firms, by their definition, have no agency costs. at the other extreme a
3、re firms whose managers are paid employees with no equity in the firm. in between are firms where the managers own some, but not all, of their firms equity. agency costs arise when the interests of the firms managers are not aligned with those of the firms owners, and take the form of preference for
4、 on-the-job perks, shirking, and making self-interested and entrenched decisions that reduce shareholder wealth. the magnitude of these costs is limited by how well the owners and delegated third parties, such as banks, monitor the actions of the outside managers. to illustrate, consider those firms
5、 where a single owner controls 100 percent of the stock but hires an outsider to manage the business. on the one hand, agency costs may be small because the sole owner can internalize all monitoring costs and has the right to hire and fire the manager. more specifically, such an owner incurs 100 per
6、cent of the monitoring costs and receives 100 percent of the resulting benefits. on the other hand, the sole owner may not be able to monitor perfectly for the same reasons that he or she hired an outside manager, such as lack of time or ability. owners of small firms typically lack financial sophis
7、tication, and may not be capable of performing random audits or fully understanding the operating or financial results. consequently, these firms incur residual agency costs. if these costs are significant, they must reflect a failure of the owners monitoring activities. potential explanations for t
8、his failure are lax monitoring by the owners and the lack of an adequate monitoring technology available for the owners. in this case, the separation of the management function initiation and implementation versus the control function by nonmanaging owners/shareholders ratification and monitoring, a
9、s suggested by fama and jensen 1983a, 1983b, may not be complete or effective. thus, residual agency costs are still expected in a sole owner firm when the manager is an outsider. agency costs attributable to the divergence of interests vary inversely with the managers ownership stake. as the number
10、 of shareholders increases from one, the ownership of the owner/manager falls to , where 0 1. because the manager gains 100 percent of each dollar spent on perks, but only percent of each dollar in firm profit, the manager who owns less than 100 percent of the firm has the incentive to consume perks
11、 rather than to imize the value of the firm to all shareholders. at the extreme is the manager with zero ownership 0, who gains 100 percent of perquisite consumption, but zero percent of firm profits in the case when salary is independent of firm performance. aggregate expenditure on monitoring by t
12、he nonmanaging shareholders decreases as their individual ownership shares decline. this is due to the well-known free-rider problem in spending for quasi-public goods, such as monitoring effort. each monitoring shareholder, with ownership i must incur 100 percent of the monitoring costs, but realiz
13、es only i percent of the monitoring benefits (in the form of reduced agency costs). a nonmonitoring shareholder, however, enjoys the full benefits of a monitoring shareholders activity without incurring any monitoring cost. thus, as the number of nonmanager shareholders increases, aggregate expendit
14、ure on monitoring declines, and the magnitude of owner-manager agency-cost problems increases. offsetting this relationship are concerns among shareholders about an increase in the probability that the firm will be unable to pay off bank debt or secure future financing from the same or new investors
15、, which may produce some restraint in agency behavior. however, as noted by williams 1987, these countervailing forces to agency behavior are expected to decline in effectiveness when the firm is not in imminent danger of insolvency to summarize, against the null hypothesis that agency costs are ind
16、ependent of the ownership and control structure,1 we postulate the following hypotheses derived from agency theory when compared to the base case: iagency costs are higher at firms whose managers own none of the firms equity, ii agency costs are an inverse function of the managers ownership stake, a
17、nd iii agency costs are an increasing function of the number of nonmanager shareholders. ii. data our empirical approach utilizes two fundamental assumptions about agency costs: 1afirm managed by a 100 percent owner incurs zero agency costs and, 2 agency costs can be measured as the difference in th
18、e efficiency of an imperfectly aligned firm and the efficiency of a perfectly aligned firm. to operationalize this approach for measuring agency costs, we need certain data inputs: i data on firm efficiency measures; ii data on firm ownership structure, including a set of firms that are 100 percent
19、owned by managers; and iii data on control variables, including firm size, characteristics, and monitoring technology. of these data requirements, the most demanding in terms of availability is item ii because sole-ownership firms typically are not publicly listed, and because financial information
20、on u.s. private firms usually is not available to the public. the federal reserve boards national survey of small business finances nssbf, fortunately, does provide financial information about privately held firms, including their ownership structure, and does include a set of firms entirely owned b
21、y managers. consequently, we use data from the nssbf to measure agency costs. the nssbf is a survey conducted by the federal reserve board to gather information about small businesses, which have largely been ignored in the academic literature because of the limited availability of data. the survey
22、collected detailed information from a sample of 4,637 firms that is broadly representative of approximately 5 million small nonfarm, nonfinancial businesses operating in the united states as of year-end 1992. cole and wolken 1995 provide detailed information about the data available from nssbf. for
23、this study, we limit our analysis to small c-corporations, collecting information on the governance structure, management alignment, extent of shareholder and external monitoring, size, and financial information. we focus on corporations to minimize problems associated with the financial statements
24、of proprietorships, which typically commingle personal and business funds. we eliminate partnerships and s-corporations because, unlike c-corporations, they are not subject to corporate taxation, and this may lead owner-managers to take compensation in the form of partner distributions or dividends
25、rather than salary expense because there is no double taxation of such earnings at the firm level. by focusing solely on c-corporations, we avoid the complications of comparing operating expenses across organizational forms. this restriction on the nssbf database yields an analysis sample of 1,708 f
26、irms. a. agency costs to measure agency costs of the firm, we use two alternative efficiency ratios that frequently appear in the accounting and financial economics literature: the expense ratio, which is operating expense scaled by annual sales, and the asset utilization ratio, which is annual sale
27、s divided by total assets. the first ratio is a measure of how effectively the firms management controls operating costs, including excessive perquisite consumption, and other direct agency costs. more precisely, the difference in the ratios of a firm with a certain ownership and management structur
28、e and the no-agency-cost base case firm, multiplied by the assets of the former, gives the excess agency cost related expense in dollars. the second ratio is a measure of how effectively the firms management deploys its assets. in contrast to the expense ratio, agency costs are inversely related to
29、the sales-to-asset ratio. a firm whose sales-to-asset ratio is lower than the base case firm experiences positive agency cost. these costs arise because the manager acts in some or all of the following ways: makes poor investment decisions, exerts insufficient effort, resulting in lower revenues; co
30、nsumes executive perquisites, so that the firm purchases unproductive assets, such as excessively fancy office space, office furnishing, automobiles, and resort properties. these efficiency ratios are not measured without error. sources of measurement error include differences in the accounting meth
31、ods chosen with respect to the recognition and timing of revenues and costs, poor recordkeeping typical of small businesses, and the tendency of small-business owners to exercise flexibility with respect to certain cost items. for example, owners may raise/lower expenses, including their own pay, wh
32、en profits are high/low. fortunately, these items are sources of random measurement errors that may be reduced with a larger sample across firms in different industries and age. b. ownership structure the corporate form of organization, with the limited-liability provision that makes it more efficie
33、nt for risk-sharing than proprietorships or partnerships, allows the firm to expand and raise funds from a large number of investors.5 thus, it has a richer set of ownership and management structures. the nssbf provides four variables that we use to capture various aspects of the ownership structure
34、 of small-business corporations: i the ownership share of the primary owner, ii an indicator for firms where a single family controls more than 50 percent of the firms shares, iii the number of nonmanager shareholders, and, iv an indicator for firms managed by a shareholder rather than an outsider.
35、according to theory, agency costs should be inversely related to the ownership share of the primary owner. for a primary owner who is also the firms manager, the incentive to consume perquisites declines as his ownership share rises, because his share of the firms profits rises with ownership while
36、his benefits from perquisite consumption are constant. for a primary owner who employs an outside manager, the gains from monitoring in the form of reduced agency costs increase with his ownership stake. here, the primary owner fulfills the monitoring role that large blockholders perform at publicly
37、 traded corporations. agency costs should be lower at firms where a single family controls more than 50 percent of the firms equity. at a small, closely held corporation where a single family controls the firm, the controlling family also fulfills the monitoring role that large blockholders perform
38、at publicly traded corporations. due to more diffused ownership among older businesses with larger families, however, monitoring by family members whose interests may not always be aligned should be less effective than monitoring by a sole owner. agency costs should increase with the number of nonma
39、nager shareholders. as the number of shareholders increases, the free-rider problem reduces the incentives for limited-liability shareholders to monitor. with less monitoring, agency costs increase. hence, we hypothesize that the expense and asset-utilization ratios should be positively and negative
40、ly related to the natural logarithm of one plus the number of nonmanaging shareholders, respectively. finally, agency costs should be higher at firms managed by an outsider. this relationship follows directly from the agency theory of jensen and meckling 1976. as noted above, this is the extreme cas
41、e where the manager gains 100 percent of perquisite consumption, but little of the firms profits.译文代理成本和股权结构 资料来源:财务杂志2000年2月第1期 作者:james s. ang, rebel a. cole, and james wuh lin 1、小企业的代理成本 与上市公司相比,小企业与代理成本的程式化理论模型描述的公司类型更相近,由jensen和meckling1976提出。一种极端的股东与管理者结构是公司中管理者拥有100%的股权。这些公司,他们的解释是没有代理成本。另外一种
42、极端是管理者作为被支付的受雇者在公司中没有股票。处在公司的两者间的是管理者持有一部分股权,但不是公司的所有。 代理成本的产生是当公司管理层与所有者的利益不一致时,采取的以减少股东财富的方式如在职消费的偏好,因懒惰而逃避工作,制定些不可更改的决定以谋取自身的利益。这些成本的巨大受限于所有者是否很好地授权第三方如银行往来监督外部管理者的行为。 为了论证这个事实,假设这些公司是由一个所有者持有100%的股票,但雇佣一个外人去管理。一方面,代理成本由于独立所有者有权雇佣和解雇管理者使监督成本内在化而可能较小。更具体些,这样的所有者会招致100%的监督成本由此收到由这个成本产生的100%的收益。另一方面,独立所有者也许不能很好地监督由于相同原因雇佣的外部管理者,如他或她缺乏时间或者动力。小企业的所有者通常缺乏复杂的财务头脑,有可能没有能力执行任意的审计或完全理解经营或财务的结果。因此,这些公司出现了剩余的代理成本。如果这些成本是不可忽略的,他们就必须反映出所有者监督活动的失败之处。这个失败的潜在解释是所有者的不严格的监督以及缺乏可用的能充分监督的技术,在这种情况下,fama和jensen1983提出,管理者的作用(实施和执行)和不参与管理的股东或所有者的控制作用(批准和监控)之间的分离,也许并不完
温馨提示
- 1. 本站所有资源如无特殊说明,都需要本地电脑安装OFFICE2007和PDF阅读器。图纸软件为CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.压缩文件请下载最新的WinRAR软件解压。
- 2. 本站的文档不包含任何第三方提供的附件图纸等,如果需要附件,请联系上传者。文件的所有权益归上传用户所有。
- 3. 本站RAR压缩包中若带图纸,网页内容里面会有图纸预览,若没有图纸预览就没有图纸。
- 4. 未经权益所有人同意不得将文件中的内容挪作商业或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文库网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对用户上传分享的文档内容本身不做任何修改或编辑,并不能对任何下载内容负责。
- 6. 下载文件中如有侵权或不适当内容,请与我们联系,我们立即纠正。
- 7. 本站不保证下载资源的准确性、安全性和完整性, 同时也不承担用户因使用这些下载资源对自己和他人造成任何形式的伤害或损失。
最新文档
- 肝血管外皮细胞瘤
- 拆迁安置房交易与补偿款结算专项合同
- 茶叶进出口代理合同样本
- 城市道路改造出渣车劳务分包及交通疏导合同
- 股权回购拆伙协议书范本
- 休闲餐饮区商铺租赁合同范本含卫生安全条款
- 电力变压器安装与设备调试服务协议
- 车辆改装设计公司股权购买合同
- 金融租赁第三方担保合作合同
- 环保设施建设拆迁补偿与环保产业房产买卖合同
- 2025年继续教育公需课必修课考试题库附含参考答案
- 渐进多焦点镜片设计特点
- 合肥市2025届高三年级5月教学质量检测(合肥三模)物理试题+答案
- 【MOOC】大学物理-力学、电磁学-重庆大学 中国大学慕课MOOC答案
- 《基于VerilogHDL的乐曲演奏电路设计》
- 保护性约束患者的护理-PPT课件
- 酸碱平衡判断(杜斌教授)血气分析六步法
- 延安整风运动历史背景基本情况
- RTO使用说明书
- 矿坑涌水量的预测方法 -(解析法)
- 有限空间作业审批
评论
0/150
提交评论